Targeted information and limited attention

AuthorShuo Liu,Andreas Hefti
Published date01 June 2020
Date01 June 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12319
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.51, No. 2, Summer 2020
pp. 402–420
Targeted information and limited attention
Andreas Hefti
and
Shuo Liu∗∗
We examine the implications of limited consumer attention for the targeting decisions of com-
peting firms. Limited attention alters the strategic role of information provision as firms may be-
come incentivized to behave as mass advertisers, despite perfect targeting abilities. We analyze
the consequences of limited attention for targeting, strategic pricing, market shares, attention
competition between firms, and the value of marketing data to firms. Accounting for limited at-
tention in an otherwise standard targeting framework can explain several recent key issues from
the advertising industry, such as consumer-side information overload or the increased usage of
ad blocking tools.
1. Introduction
Modern information systems, above all the Internet, allow sellers to gather an enormous
amount of data about their potential customers. In principle, such data allow firms to target their
ads toward precisely identified subsamples of consumers. Advertising research leaves little doubt
that targeted information has become a major source of advertising revenue. Large businesses
such as Axciom, IRI, and Nielsen earn their money by selling consumer data to individual com-
panies. Sponsored search advertising, allowing firms to advertise to consumers who indicate an
interest through their web search queries, has become “the largest source of revenues for search
engines” (Ghose and Yang, 2009). According to the annual report by the Interactive Advertis-
ing Bureau (IAB), search advertising alone already has a steady 40% of total digital ad revenue,
which was about $ 6.76 billion in 2006 and nearly tripled to $ 18.81 billion in 2014. Simi-
University of Zurich, Zurich University of Applied Science; andreas.hefti@econ.uzh.ch.
∗∗Peking University; shuo.liu@gsm.pku.edu.cn.
The authors are grateful to Jean-Michel Benkert, Alessandro Bonatti, Andrea Canidio, Fabrizio Germano, Julia Grünseis,
Igor Letina, Armin Schmutzler, Aleksei Smirnov, Philipp Strack, and seminar participants at the University of Zurich,
Swiss IO Day 2015 (Bern), the EEA Annual Congress 2016 (Geneva), the EARIE Annual Conference 2016 (Lisbon),and
the XXXI Jornadas de Economía Industrial (Palma) for discussions and useful suggestions. They thank John Christian
and Danielle Adams-Hausheer for proof-reading. They are also very thankful for the many helpful suggestions and
critical remarks by two anonymous referees and the journal editor, Mark Armstrong. Liu acknowledges the financial
support from the Key Laboratory of Mathematical Economics and Quantitative Finance(Peking University), the Ministry
of Education of China. Hefti thanks Ines Brunner for her support.
402 © 2020, The RAND Corporation.
HEFTI AND LIU / 403
larly, sponsored advertising has grown annually by around 30% from $ 1.12 billion in 2011 to
$ 1.88 billion in 2013, and is expected to grow further.1
Given the rich datasets about a firm’s potential customers and the broad array of information-
sharing technologies, including email, SMS, tweeting, and social networks, it may come as a
surprise that several recent press releases have substantially challenged whether real-world tar-
geting behavior really is beneficial for firms and consumers.2If the data about consumers is so
comprehensive and detailed, and tailored advertising is better and cheaper as ever before,3why
do so many consumers persistently complain about being overwhelmedby ads that seem to be of
little relevance to them, whereas firms are apparently targeting their messages far less accurately
than they could?4
In this article, we show that such puzzling observations can be explained by means of a
stylized competition model of targeted information when the standard presumption of unlimited
consumer attention is relaxed. Attention, as a central concept of cognition, has long been investi-
gated by psychology and neuroscience. Beginning with Miller (1956), there isextensive evidence
that people have limited attention, meaning that they fail to recognize all the information they
are exposed to once a certain threshold is reached. Given the superabundance of information
stimuli generated by modern advertising, limited attention, therefore, seems a particularly rele-
vant concept in a competition context. Indeed, the dominant and persistent preoccupation of the
advertising industry that a seller’s messages could simply be overlooked by the consumers they
were intended for implies clearly that limited consumer attention is a critical factor in markets
featuring targeted information.5
Main results. We study the effectsof limited consumer attention in a targeting context by
adopting a standard duopoly Hotelling framework with ex ante uninformed consumers. Besides
competing in prices, both firms need to choose which consumers to target with their messages,
where targeting is a costly activity. Consumers, in turn, always choose their best perceived prod-
uct. The standard (implicit) assumption of unlimited attention declares that consumers are al-
ways able to register and memorize any piece of information they are exposed to. By contrast,
attention-constrained consumers may perceive only a subset of all the information available to
them. Applied to our duopoly framework, the notion of limited attention means that consumers
will perceive at most one of the firms when making their final purchase decisions.
Our main results, Theorems 1 and 2, show that consumer inattention has a profound impact
on the equilibrium behavior of the firms. In particular, with attention-constrained consumers
and sufficiently low information costs, firms strategically choose to behave as if they were mass
advertisers, flooding the entire market with their messages, without considering consumer pref-
erences in detail, and despite an infinitely precise targeting technology. This is antipodal to the
standard prediction resulting from unlimited attention, where competition disciplines both firms
to send their messages exclusively to their prime consumers (i.e., the consumers to whom the
respective firm offers the most preferred option), even in presence of an arbitrarily small in-
formation cost. The driving force behind this discrepancy is that information targeted at prime
consumers works as an efficient shield against wastefulbusiness-stealing if and only if consumers
pay attention to every piece of information they see. In other words, limited attention annihilates
1Data available online on www.iab.com/insights and www.emarketer.com. See Yao and Mela (2011) for similar
facts on the importance of sponsored search in advertising, and Evans (2009) for a general survey on advertising data.
2Examples include the articles “Does sponsored content work for advertisers?,” Wall Street Journal, March 23,
2014 and “Does targeting work?,” The Ad Contrarian, Feb01, 2012, and the IAB report “Online consumers view and
usage of ad blocking technologies,” Sep 2014. Farahat (2013) showsthat previous studies on targeted advertising may
have largely overestimatedits effectiveness due to not accounting for selection bias.
3See, for example, “How online advertisers read your mind,”The Economist, Sep 2014.
4See, for example, a practitioner’s report posted on the website AdEspresso (available on www.adespresso.com/
blog).
5See, for example, “Advertising and technology,” The Economist, Sep 2014, Special Report.
C
The RAND Corporation 2020.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT