Target Information Asymmetry and Acquisition Price

AuthorLin Li,Wilson H.S. Tong,Peter Cheng
Published date01 July 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jbfa.12202
Date01 July 2016
Journal of Business Finance & Accounting
Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 43(7) & (8), 976–1016, July/August 2016, 0306-686X
doi: 10.1111/jbfa.12202
Target Information Asymmetry
and Acquisition Price
PETER CHENG,LIN LIANDWILSON H.S. TONG
Abstract: This study investigates the effects of target information asymmetry in a takeover
transaction. We find that a target with more information asymmetry receives a larger bid
premium from the acquirer. We examine the response of the acquirer’s investors to the bid to
clarify whether the larger bid premium is an overpayment by the acquirer. We observe that the
acquirer’s investors respond more positively to the acquisition of an opaque target, indicating
that the market recognizes the acquirer’s valuation of the opaque target and agrees with the
offer price. Our results indicate that corporate takeovers help to resolve asymmetric information
in the capital market.
Keywords: information asymmetry, price discount, bid premium, acquirer return
1. INTRODUCTION
The effects of information asymmetry on asset pricing have been widely examined
in both accounting and finance studies. An extensive body of literature shows that
equities with high information asymmetry are priced at discounts by investors (e.g.,
Glosten and Milgrom, 1985; Hertzel and Smith, 1993; and O’Hara, 2003). In the
takeover market, studies indicate that firms with low valuations often become desirable
takeover targets (e.g., Grossman and Hart, 1981; and Shleifer and Vishny, 2003).
Consequently, this suggests the possibility that firms with asymmetric information may
become targets for acquisition. Kraakman (1988) argues that certain firms are perma-
nently underpriced and that pricing discounts can only be corrected by transactions
that redeem shares for asset values, such as takeovers, privatization, or liquidation.
Draper and Paudyal (2008) propose that undervalued firms may announce takeover
The first author is at the Faculty of Management and Hospitality, Technological and Higher Education
Institute of Hong Kong. The second and third authors are at the School of Accounting and Finance, Faculty
of Business, Hong Kong Polytechnic University. This paper is part of Li’s dissertation at The Hong Kong
Polytechnic University under the guidance of the other authors. We gratefully acknowledge the helpful
comments from an anonymous referee and especially Ronan Powell (Associate Editor) whose insightful
suggestions have tremendously improved the paper. In addition, we thank Peter F. Chen, Ying Foon Chow,
Gang Li, Yong Zhang, seminar participants at The Hong Kong Polytechnic University, and conference
participants at the 2008 and 2009 European Financial Management Association (EFMA) Annual meetings,
and the 2013 Journal of Contemporary Accounting and Economics (JCAE) Symposium. (Paper received
March 2014, revised revision accepted March 2016).
Address for correspondence: Lin Li, School of Accounting and Finance, Faculty of Business, Hong Kong
Polytechnic University, Kowloon, Hong Kong.
e-mail: jack.li@polyu.edu.hk
C
2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 976
TARGET INFORMATION ASYMMETRY AND ACQUISITION PRICE 977
bids to attract the attention of investors, with a view to increasing the share price
through revaluation. As such, the takeover market can play a role in eliminating
valuation discounts due to information asymmetry that may not be corrected by the
target itself. The classic paper of Bradley et al. (1983) also discusses this issue and refers
to the target firms facing serious information asymmetry as ‘sitting on a gold mine’.
In this paper, we examine the role of takeovers in resolving asymmetric information
among participants in the capital market. We begin the analysis by considering a
situation in which the equity value of a target is discounted by the market due to
information asymmetry. An acquirer with more and better information about the
target than the market views the market discount as an opportunity for a bargain.
To avoid potential competitive bids and, in particular, to ensure the success of the
deal, the acquirer negotiates with the target by offering a price premium over the
target’s current market price. This ‘premium’ offer is attractive as the target may find
it difficult to credibly convey its true value to the market. Yet, the deal is also profitable
for the acquirer as the bid price will still be less than the true net value of the target,
let alone the possible gain from a merger synergy.
This simple framework generates a rich set of testable hypotheses. First, given that
greater information asymmetry increases the market discount, the bid premium can
appear to increase with the target’s information asymmetry. Second, the acquirer’s
announcement return also increases with the target’s information asymmetry as the
acquisition is viewed as a bargain to the acquirer due to the greater market discount.1
We conduct empirical tests of our predictions using a sample of 1,612 acquisitions
announced during the period 1986–2006. We define the bid premium received by the
target as the premium of the offer price relative to the market price of the target’s
shares four weeks prior to the bid announcement. We measure a target’s information
asymmetry, as perceived by market investors, using a set of proxies, including the bid–ask
spread, the number of analysts following the target, analyst forecast error, and forecast
dispersion.
The empirical results confirm our predictions. The proxies of the target’s infor-
mation asymmetry are positively associated with the bid premium and the acquirer’s
announcement returns, irrespective of the payment method. Furthermore, the acquir-
ers earn mildly positive returns when acquiring the most opaque targets. In contrast,
they realize significantly negative returns when acquiring the least opaque (most
transparent) targets.2Furthermore, we find greater post-takeover bidder operating
performance improvements for deals involving more opaque targets.
We conduct additional tests on the sensitivity of the bid premium on the target’s
information quality. First, we contrast the periods with and without merger waves.
Under a hot takeover market, we expect to, and do, observe an increase in the
bid premium sensitivity on target information asymmetry as acquirers tend to bid
more aggressively. Second, we contrast the periods before and after the enactment of
the Sarbanes–Oxley Act (SOX) in 2002. When investors are better protected under
SOX, the market may discount the opaque target less, leading to a decrease in
the bid premium sensitivity to target information asymmetry, and we do find the
corresponding supportive evidence. These two tests have high discriminatory power
1 This is consistent with Chang (1998), who reports larger abnormal returns to deals involving private
targets, which are presumably more opaque relative to public targets.
2 The stylized fact is that acquirers generally earn zero or mildly negative returns during the takeover
announcement period. See, for example, Jensen and Ruback (1983) and Andrade et al. (2001).
C
2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
978 CHENG, LI AND TONG
because if the link between the bid premium and the target’s information asymmetry
is spurious, merger waves and SOX should affect the bid premium across the board
only, but not the bid premium sensitivity.
Taken together, our results show that the market recognizes the acquirer’s ability to
identify an undervalued opaque target and make the acquisition. The seemingly high
bid premium paid for the opaque target is not due to an overpayment by the acquirer
but rather to the market discount of the opaque target. Therefore, corporate takeovers
play a significant role in resolving asymmetric information in the capital market by
spotting and successfully acquiring opaque targets discounted by the market.3
Our study is closely related to several recent studies. Raman et al. (2013) examine
the impact of the target’s earnings quality on the bidder’s takeover decision. They
find that targets with low earnings quality, captured in the asymmetric information
component of the target’s accrual volatility, receive high bid premiums in negotiated
inter-industry acquisitions. Their study focuses on how the target’s earnings quality
affects the acquirer’s takeover decisions, the payment method, and takeover pre-
miums, whereas our study focuses on how corporate takeovers resolve the target’s
information asymmetry problem. To the extent that earnings quality captures only
one aspect of the information quality of a firm, our study takes a more general
and comprehensive perspective in addressing the role of the target’s information
asymmetry in the takeover market.4
Another subtle, but more important difference is that when Raman et al. (2013)
examine the target’s earnings quality, they implicitly define the target’s information
asymmetry from the acquirer’s perspective and examine how it affects the acquirer’s
takeover decisions.5In contrast, we define the target’s overall information quality
from the market’s perspective (necessitating that a more comprehensive set of market
information proxies be measured), and we suggest that the associations in question
hold even when the acquirer has perfect information about the target. This subtle
difference leads to our very different interpretations of the common finding that
the bid premium is higher for a target with lower information quality. For Raman
et al. (2013), the poor information (earnings) quality induces the acquirer to uncover
information on the target through negotiations. This information is likely to be value-
enhancing, and this value is reflected in a higher bid premium. As such, Raman et al.
(2013) implicitly assume away the possibility of overbidding, and thus do not carry out
bid announcement tests, as we have done in this paper.6
In contrast to Raman et al’.s (2013) focus on the acquirer’s perspective of the tar-
get’s information asymmetry, we make a standing assumption regarding the acquirer’s
3 Naturally, our analysis does not dispute the synergetic function of the takeover market but only focuses
on another function of the takeover market in resolving information asymmetry.
4 Ball and Shivakumar (2008) find that the average quarterly earnings announcement is associated with
only approximately 1–2% of the annual information that drives the stock price, suggesting that reported
earnings do not provide much timely new information to the stock market. Hu et al. (2014) find that
information asymmetry decreases for firms that cease to provide earnings guidance. As such, poor earnings
quality contributes as only one aspect among other factors in the information asymmetry problem of a firm.
5 In explaining the constructs of the information asymmetry proxies, they state in footnote 22 that ‘(the
proxies) will be insufficient to comprehensively capture aspects of information asymmetry between acquirers
and targets or of symmetric uncertainty’ (emphasis added).
6 A recent paper by McNichols and Stubben (2015) uses almost exactly the same measure of earnings quality
as Raman et al. and finds that the announcement returns are actually higher for the acquirer if the target
has a higher earnings quality. This finding seems to be inconsistent with the value-enhancing argument of
Raman et al. (2013).
C
2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT