Tacit Collusion: The Neglected Experimental Evidence

Published date01 September 2015
Date01 September 2015
AuthorChristoph Engel
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jels.12080
Tacit Collusion: The Neglected
Experimental Evidence
Christoph Engel*
Both in the United States and in Europe, antitrust authorities prohibit merger not only if
the merged entity, in and of itself, is no longer sufficiently controlled by competition, but
also if, post merger, the market structure has changed such that “tacit collusion” or
“coordinated effects” become disturbingly more likely. It seems that antitrust neglects the
fact that for more than 50 years, economists have been doing experiments on this very
question. Almost any conceivable determinant of higher or lower collusion has been tested.
This article standardizes the evidence by way of a meta-study, and relates experimental
findings as closely as possible to antitrust doctrine.
I. The Issue
Normally, hard scientific evidence on legal issues is a seriously scarce resource. More
than one empirical publication on a precisely defined doctrinal question is a rare event.
Against this backdrop, a problem in antitrust is salient. Both in the United States and in
Europe, antitrust authorities prohibit merger not only if the merged entity, in and of
itself, is no longer sufficiently controlled by competition. The authorities also intervene
if, post merger, the market structure has changed such that “tacit collusion” becomes
disturbingly more likely. This can be seen as a precautionary measure. Collusion in gen-
eral, and tacit collusion in particular, is hard to detect, and even harder to control by
authorities bound by the rule of law. Therefore, the antitrust authorities do not wait
until market participants actually team up against the opposite market side, and against
society at large; rather, they preempt later anticompetitive behavior by prohibiting the
further concentration of a market.
Antitrust authorities mainly use the traditional doctrinal approach to assess whether
a proposed merger would significantly increase the risk of tacit collusion. Based on their
experiences in dealing with mergers in narrow markets, both in the United States and in
Europe, the authorities have published catalogues of potentially relevant factors (U.S.
*Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods, Kurt-Schumacher-Straße 10, D 53113 Bonn; email:
engel@coll.mpg.de.
537
Journal of Empirical Legal Studies
Volume 12, Issue 3, 537–577, September 2015
Merger Guidelines;
1
E.U. Merger Guidelines
2
). On the initiative of the chief economist,
the E.U. Commission also relies on game theory for this purpose (Ivaldi et al. 2003).
There also is rich econometric evidence (Feuerstein 2005) and a host of case studies in
the economics literature (Levenstein & Suslow 2006). Yet this does not exhaust the avail-
able evidence. On this prognostic question, economists, for more than 50 years, have con-
ducted experiments. Almost any conceivable determinant of higher or lower collusion has
been tested. This solid body of evidence is almost untapped by the legal community. Anti-
trust authorities appear to take little notice of the fact that one of their thorniest empiri-
cal questions has already been thoroughly investigated by a neighboring discipline.
This article makes the evidence available. It standardizes the findings by way of a
meta-study, and it matches the experimental findings as closely as possible to doctrine. In
preparation, the key concepts of the doctrine of tacit collusion in the United States and in
Europe are reported (Section II), and the methodology of the experiments, and of the
meta-study summarizing this literature, is explained (Section III). Antitrust can capitalize
on the experimental evidence at two levels. It is most helpful in evaluating and further
developing the guidelines that authorities on both sides of the Atlantic have issued for
assessing the “coordinated effects” of mergers. The individual criteria in these checklists
can be related to the experimental evidence. More importantly, the relative importance of
these criteria can be determined (Section IV). Individual cases combine these criteria in idi-
osyncratic ways. Although many parameter constellations have been tested experimentally,
an experimental result on exactly the parameter combination of a given case is often not avail-
able.Basedonthemeta-study,itissometimespossibletopredicttheimportanceofspecic
factor combinations for the risk of tacit collusion, but the data on multiple interactions are
usually not significant. A statistically less demanding approach is multiple regression. It intro-
duces the features of the case as controls and checks whether a reduction in the number of
suppliers still substantially increases the risk of collusion. The power, and the limits, of the
approach are demonstrated with respect to the European landmark case on tacit collusion,
the Airtours ruling (Section V). Meta-analysis often is used to check whether the existing body
of evidence suffers from discernible bias since studies that have found the desired effect were
more likely to be published. Happily, with these data, there is not much reason for this con-
cern. However, since experimental data are, by design, only analogous to the issue in the field
one wants to understand, external validity warrants discussion (Section VI).
II. Doctrine
Under Section 7 of the Clayton Act, mergers are prohibited if their effect “may be sub-
stantially to lessen competition, or to tend to create a monopoly” (15 U.S.C. 18). Under
1
Department of Justice, Federal Trade Commission, Antitrust Division, 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines of
September 10, 1992, 57 FR 41552, Preface; Horizontal Merger Guidelines of August 19, 2010, available at
<http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/guidelines/hmg-2010.html>.
2
Guidelines on the Assessment of Horizontal Mergers Under the Council Regulation on the Control of Concen-
trations Between Undertakings, OJ 2004 C 31/5.
538 Engel
Section 1 of the Sherman Act, mergers are prohibited if they constitute a “contract,
combination ..., or conspiracy in restraint of trade” (15 U.S.C. 1). Both the Antitrust
Division of the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission have jurisdic-
tion to intervene. To increase predictability, in 1992 both authorities issued joint guide-
lines on the treatment of horizontal mergers. Although most of these guidelines were a
restatement of court decisions and administrative practice, the section on potential coor-
dinated and unilateral effects of mergers was meant to innovate (U.S. Merger Guidelines
1992, Preface). In light of both the experiences of the authorities and the evolution of
the accompanying scholarly debates, in 2010 the guidelines were revised and extended
(U.S. Merger Guidelines 2010).
The guidelines stress that the anticompetitive effects of merger are not confined
to increased market power for the new commercial unit (U.S. Merger Guidelines 2010,
#1). Besides “unilateral effects,” a merger may also be challenged if it creates a risk of
“coordinated effects” (U.S. Merger Guidelines 2010, #1). For coordinated effects, there
is no need to show that firms will explicitly team up; it suffices to make a case of
“parallel accommodating conduct.” This “includes situations in which each rival’s
response to competitive moves made by others is individually rational” (U.S. Merger
Guidelines 2010, #7). To that end, the agencies expressly engage in prediction: “The
Agencies examine whether a merger is likely to change the manner in which market
participants interact, inducing substantially more coordinated interaction” (U.S. Merger
Guidelines 2010, #7.1).
In Europe, under Article 3 II of the Merger Regulation, “a concentration which
would significantly impede effective competition, in the common market or in a sub-
stantial part of it, in particular as a result of the creation or strengthening of a domi-
nant position, shall be declared incompatible with the common market” (OJ 2004 L 24/
1). According to the case law of the European Court of Justice, the test includes situa-
tions of “collective dominance.” In the Airtours case of 2002,
3
coordinated effects were
center stage, with a rich echo in academic writing (Motta 2000; Christensen & Rabassa
2001; Haupt 2002; Overd 2002; Stroux 2002; Guerrero 2003; Nikpay & Houwen 2003;
Scott 2003; Spink & Ong 2003; Veljanovski 2004; Kokkoris 2005). However, the doctrinal
concept is as old as the Nestle/Perrier case of 1992.
4
It was approved by the European
Court of Justice in the Kali und Salz case of 1998
5
(Perez 1998; Ysewyn & Caffarra 1998).
In Airtours, the European Court of First Instance held that a merger may be pro-
hibited if, in light of “the relationship of interdependence ... the parties ... are in a
3
Court of First Instance, 6 June 2002, Airtours plc v. Commission of the European Communities, European Court
Reports 2002 II 2585.
4
Commission Decision, 22 July 1992, OJ 1992 L 356/1; see also Commission Decision, 14 December 1993, OJ
1994 L 186/38, Kali1Salz/MdK/Treuhand.
5
European Court of Justice, 31 March 1998, European Court Reports 1998 I 1519, para. 221; see also European
Court of First Instance, 25 March 1999, European Court Reports 1999 II 753, Gencor and on this case Albors-
Llorens (2000); Commission Decision, 26 October 2004, OJ 2005 L 218/6, Oracle/People Soft and on this case
Pflanz (2005).
539Tacit Collusion

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT