SURVEY: Oil economics turned upside down as low prices fail to bring about production cuts

Published date01 August 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/oet.12497
Date01 August 2017
SURVEY
Lowoilpricesweremeanttoresultintheshutting-inofhigh-costproduction,especiallyintheUS,allowingsupplyand
demand to rebalance at a much higher oil price. Instead , we have rising production f rom the US and else where and
continuing low prices. e link between low crude prices and production in a number of key producers across the world
is examined by Oil and Energy Trends’ Consulting Editor, Dr Paul McDonald.
Oil economics turned upside down as low prices fail to bring about
production cuts
Low oil prices fail to curb production
Oil markets used to operate on the principle that a
fallinoilpricescausedbyanexcessofsupplyover
demand could be reversed by cutting production; and
that the reduction wou ld come primarily f rom the pro-
duction with the highest costs, leaving the lowest-cost
output more or less unaected. is was what was sup-
posed to happen following the fall in crude oil prices
that began in 2014, resulting in both the shutting-in
of marginal product ion across the world and t he dis-
couraging of new pro duction in frontier regions , notably
the shale oilelds of the US, leaving low-cost produc-
tion in areas like the Middle East and North Africa
untouched, aer which the price of crude was meant to
go back up.
Instead, aer falling a little, most high-cost produc-
tion, including US shale, rose and went on increasing
as crude oil prices fell. In November 2016, OPEC and
a few other oil-producing countries agreed to reduce
their production amid condent predictions of a fall i n
high-costproductionandariseinprices.Neitherhap-
pened. Several OPEC countries shut-in low production:
prices meanwhile continued to decline.
What went wrong?
is was not the rst time that production and prices
had not behaved as they were meant to. In March 1983,
OPEC tried to stem a slide in oil prices by agreeing a
system of country production quotas under a collective
ceiling of 17.5mn bpd for the group, with the further
promise that Saudi Arabia would additionally adjust its
production downwards to prevent a surplus of supply
that would force down global crude prices further.
e target in particular was North Sea oil production,
which had grown rapidly under the stimulus of rising oil
prices at the end of the 1970s and early-1980s, and which
was expected to fall once prices began to decline. When
this did not happen, OPEC de cided to act by cutting its
own output. Prices nevertheless continued to fall, along
with Saudi production, until Saudi Arabia was actually
producing less than the UK, whereupon it abandoned
its role as swing producer in September 1985 and there
began a price war amid r ising global production that
took crude prices down to $10/bbl and below. And still
North Sea output went on rising .
In the present era of weak prices, little has changed.
In an attempt to raise prices Saudi Arabia once more
emerged as OPEC’s swing producer in the rst half of
2017 but global prices still failed to go up. High-cost
production,thistimeintheUSandelsewhere,hasalso
carried on rising [1].
Assessing production costs
e high-cost versus low-cost argument is something
of an oversimplication. To begin with, the costs them-
selves have a number of dierent elements. ese
include:
Capital expenditure;
Operational expenditure;
Tax e s ;
Other costs.
Capital expenditure (capex) is mainly the cost of
surveying and drilling the prospect, completing the
wells and bringing them into produc tion. In the case
of oshore production t here is the cost of pro duction
platforms, which can push capex above $20/bbl: some
six-times or more than that of an oileld in parts of the
Middle East. Added to these are the costs of provid-
ing well-head processing, storage and pipeline or other
transport infrastructure for the oil, along with facilities
for the treatment of any gas, plusme asuresto prevent or
contain oil spills or any other forms of pollution.
In addition to the capex is the expenditure on the
actual production (opex), which may include the use of
third-party pipeline capacity to transport the oil to the
nearest pricing point, such as a storage terminal, as is the
case in the US. Taxesare a further potential cost, to which
may be added a host of administrative costs.
Allofthesemakeitdiculttogiveaccurategureson
the costs of oil produ ction. Moreover, costs var y from
eld to eld according to such factors as the nature of
each reservoir and the size of the reserves contained in
the eld. e cost of b orrowing money for c apex also
varies from one area to another.
ere are nevertheless some gures that may be
used as general indicators of costs, which allow some
kind of ranking of production by country. Figures
produced by Rystad Energy show a marked dierence
between the low-cost producers of the Middle East
© 2017 John Wiley& Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT