Sunk Costs and Screening: Two‐Part Tariffs in Life Insurance

Published date01 September 2020
Date01 September 2020
AuthorRobert E. Hoyt,Krzysztof Ostaszewski,James M. Carson,Cameron M. Ellis
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jori.12283
©2019 The Journal of Risk and Insurance (2019).
DOI: 10.1111/jori.12283
Sunk Costs and Screening: Two-Part Tariffs in Life
Insurance
James M. Carson
Cameron M. Ellis
Robert E. Hoyt
Krzysztof Ostaszewski
Abstract
We develop a model of insurance pricing under heterogeneous lapse rates
with asymmetric information about lapse likelihood within the context of
an optional two-part tariff as a screening device for future policyholder be-
havior. We then test for consumer self-selection using policy-level data on
life insurance backdating. We exploit randomness in the initial tariff size to
separately identify the selection and sunk cost effects of backdating on lapse
proclivity.We find that consumers who are less likely to lapse self-select into
the two-part tariff pricing structure and we also document consumer behav-
ior consistent with sunk cost fallacy.
Introduction
There are large, upfront, fixed costs to writing a life insurance policy. Both agent
commission and direct underwriting costs (e.g., fees for physicals and blood tests) are
almost fully borne by insurers a few years into contracts that may last upwards of
30 years. Because of these upfront costs, insurers can actually lose money on policies
when the consumer lapses early into the contract, even if no death benefit is ever paid
James M. Carson is at the Terry College of Business, The University of Georgia. Carson can be
contacted via e-mail: jcarson@uga.edu. CameronM. Ellis is at the Fox School of Business, Temple
University,630 Alter Hall, 1801 Liacouras Walk, Philadelphia, PA 19122. Ellis can be contacted
via e-mail: cameron.ellis@temple.edu. Robert E. Hoyt is at the Terry College of Business, The
University of Georgia.Hoyt can be contacted via e-mail: rhoyt@uga.edu. Krzysztof Ostaszewski
is at Illinois State University. Ostaszewski can be contacted via e-mail: krzysio@ilstu.edu. The
authors are grateful to Scott Atkinson, Richard Butler,David Eckles, Julio Garin, Irina Gemmo,
Josh Kinsler, Alexander Muermann, Lars Powell, Thomas Quon, David Russell, Ian Schmutte,
Art Snow, John Turner, Bill Vogt, Juan Zhang, and seminar participants at meetings of the
WorldRisk and Insurance Economics Congress (Munich August, 2015), the Southern Risk and
Insurance Association (New Orleans November, 2015), the CEAR/MRIC Behavioral Insur-
ance Workshop(Munich December, 2016), the Allied Social Science Association—ARIA Session
(Philadelphia December,2017), Cal State Fullerton, the University of Georgia, the University of
Nebraska, and St. John’s University as well as two anonymous referees for helpful comments.
1
689
689
. Vol. 87, No. 3, 689–718 (2020).
2The Journal of Risk and Insurance
out. Thus, to properly price contracts, insurers must estimate lapse risks. However,
because consumers may have knowledge about their relative lapse likelihood that
the insurer does not observe, asymmetric information arises and room for a screening
mechanism exists.
In this article, we develop a model of life insurance pricing under heterogeneous
lapse behavior with asymmetric information about lapse likelihood. We establish
the existence of a separating equilibrium under a menu of contracts containing an
optional two-part tariff. We then show the consumer’s choice serves as a screening
device for private information on lapse likelihood. Using detailed, policy-level data
on life insurance backdating as an example of our proposed optional two-part tariff,
we empirically test our model’s prediction of consumer self-selection. We use a con-
trol function approach to separately identify selection effects from potential sunk cost
fallacy.We find that consumers who choose to take part in the two-part tariff by back-
dating their policies are less likely to lapse, due to both self-selection and sunk costs.
Lapse rates in life insurance are substantial. Between 1991 and 2010, $29.7 trillion of
new individual life insurance coverage was issued in the United States. During this
same time period, $24 trillion of coverage lapsed. In a given year, for every term life
policy that ends in death or term maturation, 36 policies lapse due to nonpayment of
premiums (Purushotham, 2006). Eighty-eight percent of whole life insurance policies
never pay a death benefit (Gottlieb and Smetters, 2016). There are several theories on
why consumers lapse on their polices. This literature is well-developed and can be
condensed into: preference shocks, income shocks, policy replacement, and nonex-
pected utility explanations.
Preference shocks refer to a number of situations wherethe private value of the life in-
surance contract has changed (Fang and Kung, 2010; Liebenberg, Carson, and Dumm,
2012; Fei, Fluet, and Schlesinger, 2015).1Examples include: divorce, death of a spouse
or child, children becoming self-sufficient, increase in spousal income, etc. Income
shocks refer to consumers experiencing a negative shock to income and thereby hav-
ing insufficient funds to pay premiums. The effect of an income shock on lapse rates
is stronger in whole life insurance due to the higher premiums and presence of a
surrender value. This is referred to in the literature as the emergencyfund hypothesis
(Linton, 1932; Outreville, 1990; Kuo, Tsai,and Chen, 2003). The aptly named policy re-
placement hypothesis refers to consumers who lapse on one policy because they find
what they believe to be a better one (Outreville, 1990; Carson and Forster, 2000). The
interest rate hypothesis is a specific case of the policy replacement hypothesis where
the driver of better available policies is a change in expectations of future interest
rates (Schott, 1971; Pesando, 1974; Kuo, Tsai, and Chen, 2003).2The final category of
research on lapse rates focuses on nonexpected utility models of consumer behavior
1This reason for lapsing generally only covers negative shocks to the insurance value of the
policy. Positive shocks to preferences are typically subsumed by the policy replacement cate-
gory.
2Because insurance premiums are collected, and invested, long before benefits are paid out,
expectations about interest rates play an important part in the determination of premium
rates.
2The Journal of Risk and Insurance
690

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT