Subsidy competition and imperfect labor markets

AuthorKazuhiro Yamamoto,Tadashi Morita,Yukiko Sawada
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12400
Date01 June 2020
Published date01 June 2020
J Public Econ Theory. 2020;22:698728.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet698
|
© 2019 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Received: 27 August 2018
|
Accepted: 14 August 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12400
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Subsidy competition and imperfect labor
markets
Tadashi Morita
1
|
Yukiko Sawada
2
|
Kazuhiro Yamamoto
3
1
Faculty of Economics, Kindai
University, Kowakae, Higashiosaka,
Osaka, Japan
2
Faculty of Economics, Ryukoku
University, Kyoto, Japan
3
Graduate School of Economics, Osaka
University, Osaka, Japan
Correspondence
Tadashi Morita, Faculty of Economics,
Kindai University, Osaka 5778502, Japan.
Email: t-morita@kindai.ac.jp
Funding information
JSPS, Grant/Award Numbers:
JP15H03348, JP16H03615, JP25870925,
17K13741; RIETI
Abstract
This study presents a twocountry model of subsidy
competition for manufacturing firms under labor market
imperfections. Because subsidies affect the distribution
of firms, subsidies influence unemployment rates and
welfare in both countries. We show that when labor
market frictions are high, subsidy competition is bene-
ficial, although subsidies under subsidy competition are
inefficiently high. In the coordinated equilibrium, the
supranational authority provides a subsidy to firms that
equal the expected total search costs, which increases the
number of firms relative to laissezfaire and improves
welfare relative to laissezfaire and subsidy competition.
Finally, we find that a rise in a countrys labor market
frictions raises the equilibrium subsidy rate, affects
unemployment rates, and lowers welfare.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
In recent years, active labor market policies involving subsidies to private sector employers have
been implemented in many European Union (EU; Kluve, 2010) and Organisation for Economic
Cooperation and Development (OECD) countries (Card, Kluve, & Weber, 2010; Martin, 2015).
On the one hand, many governments provide subsidies to private firms to lower unemployment
rates, and these subsidies have been considered to have only indirect effects on foreign
countries.
1
On the other hand, the Subsidies and Countervailing Measures Agreement (SCM
Agreement) aims to control the subsidies granted by World Trade Organization (WTO)
members, which may be harmful for other countries.
2
In particular, the SCM Agreement
1
The OECD (2010) states that labor market interventions have an indirect bearing on international trade.
2
Mavroidis (2016) states that the SCM Agreement requires that WTO members avoid using two types of prohibited subsidies (i.e., local content and export
subsidies) as well as other subsidies that may adversely affect other WTO members. The SCM Agreement does not make the treatment of subsidies conditional
on their rationale. In other words, nowadays, subsidies can be counteracted regardless of their rationale.
prohibits an export subsidy or a subsidy contingent for the use of domestic over imported goods
or a subsidy seriously prejudicing the interests of another member. Indeed, a subsidy in one
country may result in another country experiencing a negative externality. In other words,
although active labor market policies aim to internalize the distortions generated by labor
market frictions, they may result in negative externalities to other countries. If the subsidy
policy in our study can be interpreted as seriously prejudicing the interests of another member,
it would be prohibited under Articles 5 and 6 of the SCM Agreement.
On the contrary, WTO and European state aid regulations permit a subsidy to firms that
offset a provencost disadvantage relative to another competition location. In our model,
governments have an incentive to provide a subsidy to firms, since labor market frictions
worsen the profitability of firms and lower welfare. In that case, the WTO allows governments
to provide subsidies to firms, which lead them into subsidy competition.
Against the background of the WTO prohibiting subsidy policies that may harm other
countries, this study investigates whether the absence of such subsidy competition is beneficial
or harmful for two countries that trade manufactured goods and face labor market
imperfections. Our study points out that a subsidy that improves the labor market imperfections
in a country brings about a negative externality to the other country. Moreover, the subsidy
rates in these two countries are strategic complements, which means that the equilibrium
subsidy rate becomes inefficiently high. Therefore, the analysis presented in this study shows
that subsidy competition is more beneficial (wasteful) than laissezfaire economics when labor
market frictions are large (small) relative to the negative externality brought about by subsidy
competition.
3,4
Thus, we show that the WTOs policy of prohibiting subsidy competition is
harmful when labor market frictions are large, even when one country brings about a negative
externality to another country under subsidy competition. Moreover, our analysis shows that
trade liberalization enlarges the negative externality of subsidy competition as well as the
possibility that subsidy competition is harmful for both countries. Thus, we further show that
recent globalization increases the possibility that the WTOs policy may be reasonable.
We construct a twocountry, twosector (manufacturing and agriculture) model in which the
markets for manufactured goods are segmented between the two countries. A specific feature of
our model is that the labor market in the manufacturing sector is assumed to be imperfect.
Firms entering the manufacturing sector search for workers to employ, and these search
activities are assumed to incur a positive search cost, which lowers the entry of operating firms
in the market. We show that in the laissezfaire economy, a government provides a subsidy to
manufacturing firms, which increases the number of operating firms and improves welfare.
Thus, when there is a positive search cost, governments have an incentive to provide subsidies
to manufacturing firms to decrease the inefficiency induced by labor market frictions.
5
Each government is assumed to provide a subsidy to maximize welfare in its own country. In
our model, an externality is generated by subsidy competition, following previous tax
competition studies, including Borck, Koh, and Pflüger (2012) and Pflüger and Suedekum
(2013). The increase in subsidies speeds up the entry of firms into the country, which intensifies
3
Andolfatto (1996), Shimer (2005), and Menzio and Shi (2011) find that the estimated values of labor market frictions (search costs for firms) in the United
States differ widely.
4
Boadway, Cuff, and Marceau (2002) show a case in which tax competition improves welfare in a model with labor market imperfections. Wilson (1999) and
Wilson and Wildasin (2004) introduce models in which tax competition improves efficiency in their comprehensive reviews of tax competition studies.
5
Costinot (2009) constructs a small open economy in which there are search frictions in labor markets and positive search costs for vacancies create a rent
distributed to employed workers. This study focuses on the effect of protectionism on the unemployment rate, showing that an increase in international trade
tax (i.e., protection policy) by a government may increase aggregate rents in a country.
MORITA ET AL.
|
699

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT