Structural Transformation and Comparative Advantage: Implications for Small Open Economies

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12398
Date01 April 2017
AuthorUnjung Whang
Published date01 April 2017
Structural Transformation and
Comparative Advantage: Implications for
Small Open Economies
Unjung Whang
1,2
1
Department of International Trade, Korea Institute for International Economic Policy (KIEP),
Sejong-si, Korea and
2
Department of Economics, University of Colorado, Boulder, CO, USA
1. INTRODUCTION
SOME rich countries seem to have relatively high productivity in agriculture than in
non-agriculture (e.g. Australia, New Zealand and the USA). Several Latin American
countries (e.g. Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Mexico and Uruguay), however, failed to achieve a
high level of income during the past half-century despite relatively high agricultural produc-
tivity, whereas some East Asian countries (e.g. Korea and Japan) successfully transformed the
economy into industrialisation despite lower agricultural productivity. To explain these pat-
terns, economists have taken one of two approaches. Most studies consider closed-economy
models where rich countries are relatively more productive in agriculture than in
non-agriculture (e.g. Restuccia et al., 2003; Caselli, 2005; Gollin et al., 2007), whereas a
smaller set of studies consider explicitly an open-economy model where the driving force is
the law of comparative advantage (e.g. Matsuyama, 1992).
1
In this paper, I refine the second
stream of literature and investigate its quantitative implications for open economies.
A starting point for this paper is Matsuyama (1992), which suggests that the relationship
between agricultural productivity and industrialisation in an open economy could be negative
because a low agricultural productivity, ceteris paribus, implies a comparative advantage in
non-agricultural sector.
2
These countries with a comparative advantage in non-agricultural
sector specialise non-agricultural goods so that labour force moves away from agricultural
sector. In contrast, a high agricultural productivity relative to the rest of the world (and hence
a comparative advantage in agriculture) pushes labour force out of manufacturing to agricul-
tural sector due to international trade, through which a country exports agricultural products
in response to importing manufacturing products.
However, Matsuyama’s (1992) model lacks solid empirical support. For instance, McMillan
and Rodrik (2011) show that the labour productivity in agricultural sector relative to non-agricul-
The author thanks Jin-hyuk Kim, James Markusen, Keith Maskus, Eun-Sun Park, Yeo Joon Yoon, Seong
Man Moon and Murat Iyigun for their insightful comments. The paper has also benefited from comments
by seminar participants in the 2012 Midwest Macroeconomics Meeting, Kyunghee University, and KIEP
seminar. The errors remain the author’s responsibility.
1
In these strands of the closed-economy literature, a positive link between agricultural productivity and
economic development can be supported by two reasons, which are associated with the fact that the
income elasticity of demand for agricultural good is less then unity (i.e. StoneGeary utility function).
First, a low agricultural productivity can impede industrialisation by delaying onset of industrialisation.
Second, an increase in agricultural productivity, other things being equal, pushes labour force out of
agricultural sector to non-agricultural sector.
2
Matsuyama’s argument was based on historical evidence from Belgium and the Netherlands (Mokyr,
1974) as well as New England and the South (Field, 1978; Wright, 1979).
©2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 743
The World Economy (2017)
doi: 10.1111/twec.12398
The World Economy
tural sector exhibits a U-shaped pattern as the economy develops. Specifically, they show that
data from India exhibit the downward sloping part of the curve, whereas French data show the
upward sloping part. This paper offers a revised Matsuyama model to show that the predictions
of the open-economy model are more complicated; however, Matsuyama’s theoretical results
continue to hold qualitatively, and more importantly, I show through the model calibration that
the quantitative effects of comparative advantage and learning-by-doing in open economy can
be substantial.
This paper considers a two-sector Ricardian model similar to the one considered by Lucas
(1988) and Matsuyama (1992), where due to learning-by-doing technology the manufacturing
sector’s total factor productivity (TFP) grows with its scale of production. Following Gollin
et al. (2007) and Restuccia et al. (2003), I allow agricultural sector to be modernised using
manufacturing output as an intermediate input to its production. Different from these articles,
however, I focus on the role of comparative advantage in an open economy as the main driv-
ing force behind structural transformation. Indeed, counterfactual analysis in this paper show s
that the role of comparative advantage in an open economy is quantitatively important for
explaining the different patterns of structural change across countries. Besides, the open-
economy aspects of structural change can complement the dominant view discussed in the
literature that the poor countries are relatively unproductive in agriculture, so that it captures
the real world more completely.
In Section 2, to motivate our study, I construct an index of revealed comparative advantage
(RCA) in agriculture as well as manufacturing, as proposed by Balassa (1965) and show that
there is a strong negative (positive) relationship between RCA in agriculture (manufacturing)
and the growth rate of manufacturing labour share in a cross section of countries. Although
this correlation is only suggestive, it is consistent with the theoretical result in Matsuyama
(1992) that there could be a negative relationship between agricultural productivity and speed
of industrialisation.
In Section 3, I present the theoretical model, show conditions for industrialisation to begin
in a subsistence economy and characterise the equilibrium and the time path of an open econ-
omy’s structural transformation. In Section 4, I calibrate the model to match the US and the
UK data on agriculture’s labour share. The calibrated model, despite being simple, accounts
fairly well for the long-run patterns, such as the evolution of agriculture’s share of total
output in the USA and the UK.
Using the 50 largest countries’ labour share data from 1961 to 2003 as a benchmark, I then
quantitatively analyse the effect of comparative advantage on structural changes. The numeri-
cal experiments show that a mere 4 per cent initial comparative advantage in the manufactur-
ing sector leads to a threefold difference in agriculture’s employment share and accounts for
roughly 15 per cent difference in the aggregate output during the sample period. Further, a 5
per cent increase in the speed of learning-by-doing can account for a factor of three difference
in agriculture’s employment share and about 18 per cent increase in aggregate output, while
learning has little effect in a closed economy.
This paper is related to the strand of literature that numerically investigates the effect of
trade on industrialisation (e.g. Echevarria, 1995; Stokey, 2001; Teignier, 2012). For instance,
Teignier simulates a neoclassical growth model to the structural transformation of the USA,
the UK and South Korea and estimates the effect of trade on consumer welfare. The differ-
ence is that in my model, productivities evolve endogenously and I focus on the effect of
comparative advantage as well as learning-by-doing in an open economy, while in the above
©2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
744 U. WHANG

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT