Structural Power, Hegemony, and State Capitalism: Limits to China’s Global Economic Power

DOI10.1177/0032329220950234
Published date01 June 2021
Date01 June 2021
Subject MatterArticles
https://doi.org/10.1177/0032329220950234
Politics & Society
2021, Vol. 49(2) 235 –267
© The Author(s) 2020
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/0032329220950234
journals.sagepub.com/home/pas
Article
Structural Power, Hegemony,
and State Capitalism: Limits
to China’s Global Economic
Power
Mingtang Liu
Johns Hopkins University
Kellee S. Tsai
Hong Kong University of Science and Technology
Abstract
A comparative historical perspective shows how globalization and the specificities
of China’s rapid growth era limit its hegemonic potential in the twenty-first century
global economy. Although state capitalism and openness to foreign capital facilitated
China’s economic transformation, interactions among three forms of capital—state,
private, and foreign—have produced developmental dynamics that constrain China’s
capacity to assume the position of the world’s economic hegemon. These include
(1) the compromised competitiveness of China’s corporate sector due to the
domination of state-owned enterprises, (2) limits on the ability of Chinese firms to
develop leading transnational corporations, and (3) early openness to and continued
dependence on foreign capital. Moreover, the party-state’s efforts to ameliorate these
constraints arouse external suspicion rather than support a Chinese-led hegemonic
order based on consent and shared interests. These historically conditioned realities
should temper expectations that China is converging teleologically toward a familiar
hegemonic role in the international economy.
Keywords
China, hegemony, globalization, state capitalism, structural power
Corresponding Author:
Kellee S. Tsai, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Clear Water Bay, Kowloon, Hong Kong
SAR.
Email: ktsai@ust.hk
950234PASXXX10.1177/0032329220950234Politics & SocietyLiu and Tsai
research-article2020
236 Politics & Society 49(2)
I believe the twenty-first century will belong to China because most centuries have
belonged to China.
Niall Ferguson (2011)
It will be impossible for China to be a strong country without an innovation-driven
economy. If we do not follow the innovation-driven path, then we will only be big, but by
no means strong.
Xi Jinping (2018)
Huawei is an instrument of the Chinese government.
Mike Pompeo (2019)
Images of China’s skyscraper-studded megacities, sleek high-speed trains, robot-oper-
ated assembly lines, cashless consumerism, and the ubiquity of AI-assisted surveil-
lance are awe-inspiring, if not unnerving to international observers. Coupled with
news headlines about China producing more than 200 unicorns (start-ups valued at
over $1 billion), such images give the sense that China’s economic and technological
ascendance is bound to continue, albeit at a more modest pace than in the previous four
decades. Traditional metrics of national wealth would suggest that China is well on its
way to becoming an economic superpower. Its establishment of the Asian Infrastructure
Investment Bank and rollout of the Belt and Road Initiative have further fueled specu-
lation about the imminence of China’s accession to a hegemonic position in the global
economy. However, regardless of Beijing’s intentions, our analysis of China’s political
economy from a comparative historical perspective reveals structural constraints on
such expectations. Globalization and the historical specificities of China’s rapid
growth era have adversely affected key indicators of its relative economic power and
undercut its potential to build a new hegemonic order in the twenty-first century. By
comparing the configuration of social forces embedded in China’s development model
with those of earlier rising powers, we argue that although state capitalism and open-
ness to foreign capital facilitated its remarkable economic transformation since the late
1970s, the dynamics of the growth process itself and the changing nature of the global
economy have generated structural constraints on China’s capacity to develop strong
transnational corporations. Combined with Western backlash to China’s rise, that
weakness poses limits on its economic influence in an age in which such corporations
play a dominant role in the global economy.
To anchor this argument analytically, we adopt Robert Cox’s broader conception of
hegemony as encompassing strong structural power, as well as the ability to generate
consent and exercise leadership in the world political economy.1 To understand the
mechanisms underlying these twin components of global hegemony, we contend that
it is necessary to examine China’s domestic political economy and the configuration
of social forces underpinning it. We start by establishing that the political economy of
China’s reform-era development is historically unprecedented. Aggregate prosperity
Liu and Tsai 237
in the world’s most populous country has been led by a strong Leninist party-state with
state-owned enterprises controlling the commanding heights of the national economy,
the relative neglect and fragmentation of domestic private capital, and a significant
presence of foreign capital following liberalizing reforms. We further observe that by
the 2000s, interactions among these three forms of capital—state, private, and for-
eign—generated three dynamics that constrain China’s relative economic power: (1)
compromised competitiveness of China’s corporate sector due to the domination of
state-owned enterprises, (2) limits on the ability of Chinese firms to develop leading
transnational corporations, and (3) early openness to and continued dependence on
foreign capital.
As the Chinese government attempted to address these structural constraints during
the 2000s, it met countervailing responses from abroad that undermine its potential for
establishing an alternative hegemonic order. First, entrenched business interests and
foreign governments sought to preserve the status quo. Second, China’s statist eco-
nomic model raised concerns about national security and elicited critiques of protec-
tionism by other major economic powers. Those dual pressures subsequently triggered
vigorous countermeasures from the West. Recognition of these historically condi-
tioned realities, taken together, should temper expectations that China is converging
teleologically toward a familiar hegemonic role in the global economy. Rather than
unipolar economic dominance by China, the contemporary world order shows signs of
multipolarity with a flattening of postwar American dominance.2
In making these claims, this article does not discount the Chinese economy’s pre-
existing performance, portend national decline, dismiss political concerns raised by
China’s external investments, or speculate about its leadership’s intentions. Instead,
we focus on elucidating the developmental paradoxes generated by China’s state-led
socialist transition and industrialization within the global economic context of the late
twentieth and early twenty-first centuries. Doing so demonstrates the analytic value of
historicizing national economic power rather than reflexively equating it with tradi-
tional metrics such as industrial output or GDP. Our focus on structural power in
global production intends not to downplay the roles of global finance and military
capabilities but to interrogate common assumptions regarding China’s economic
power and potential for global leadership. The empirical findings revealed in the pro-
cess have implications for how we situate the case of China in the study of interna-
tional relations and international political economy.
The article proceeds as follows. After noting dominant perspectives on the mea-
surement of national economic power, the first section critiques studies that engage in
ahistorical consideration of China’s rise and overlook distinguishing features of its
domestic political economy. To address those shortcomings, we propose that China’s
relative economic position and hegemonic potential should be investigated through a
thicker notion of hegemony that includes capacity to generate consent. Adopting a
comparative historical lens, the second section points out the changing indicators of
economic power over time and compares China’s developmental model and interna-
tional context with those of dominant Western powers in the preceding centuries. The
third section elaborates the structural constraints generated by China’s developmental

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT