A Strict Liability Regime for Rating Agencies

AuthorAlessio M. Pacces,Alessandro Romano
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ablj.12054
Published date01 December 2015
Date01 December 2015
A Strict Liability Regime for Rating
Agencies
Alessio M. Pacces* and Alessandro Romano**
INTRODUCTION
The behavior of Credit Rating Agencies (CRAs) has received careful
scrutiny in the past decade, particularly in the aftermath of the global
financial crisis. This is with good reason. According to the law and eco-
nomics literature, ratings are valuable for the society because they
reduce asymmetric information in finance.
1
In this perspective, the
function of CRAs is to provide investors with certifications of the quality
*Professor of Law & Finance at Erasmus School of Law, Erasmus University Rotterdam,
and Research Associate at the European Corporate Governance Institute (ECGI).
**Visiting Researcher at Yale Law School and PhD candidate at Erasmus School of Law,
Erasmus University Rotterdam, and at LUISS-Guido Carli School of Law in Rome.
A previous version of this article was published as ECGI research paper in law and a short sum-
mary of it was posted on the Harvard Law School Forum on Corporate Governance and Finan-
cial Regulation. Part of the research included in this article was carried out at the Study Center
Gerzensee of the Swiss National Bank, whose hospitality is gratefully acknowledged. This article
benefitedfrom the feedbackof participantsin the 2014 European Summer Symposiumon Eco-
nomic Theory (ESSET) in Gerzensee, the 2014 MaCCI Law and Economics Conference on
Financial Regulation and Competition in Mannheim, the 2013 Meeting of the Canadian Associ-
ationinLawandEconomicsinToronto,the15thJointSeminaroftheEuropeanAssociationof
Law and Economics and the Geneva Association in Girona, the 4th Annual Conference of the
Spanish Association of Law and Economics in Grana da, and the 11th Annual Meeting of the
German Association of Law and Economics in Bolzano. We thank Gaia Barone, Patrick Bolton,
Jeff Gordon, Alice Guerra, Martin Hellwig, Todd Henderson, Claire Hill, Giovanni Immordino,
Yair Listokin, Vyacheslav Mikhed, Marcello Puca, Pietro Reichlin, Roberta Romano, Ulrich
Schroeter, Alan Schwartz, Bob Scott, Angela Troisi, and Roland Vaubel for valuable comments
on previous versions of this work. The usual disclaimers apply.
1
See, e.g., Lawrence J. White, Markets: The Credit Rating Agencies,24J.ECON.PERSPECTIVES 211,
212–13 (2010)(“The purpose of credit rating agencies is tohelp pierce the fog of asymmetric
information by offering judgments—they prefer the word ‘opinions’—about the credit quality
V
C2015 The Authors
American Business Law Journal V
C2015 Academy of Legal Studies in Business
673
American Business Law Journal
Volume 52, Issue 4, 673–720, Winter 2015
bs_bs_banner
of financial assets, which is a form of gatekeeping.
2
CRAs are perform-
ing this beneficial role in financial markets so long as the ratings they
produce are above a certain accuracy threshold, which for simplicity we
assume to be exogenously determined by the existing forecasting tech-
nology. Ratings are informative, thus valuable, because such technology
is not available to the public. The problem of asymmetric information
applies to financial regulators too, which explains why financial regula-
tion is reliant on ratings for a number of purposes.
3
Conversely, when
they are systematically higher than warranted, ratings may fuel asset
bubbles and eventually lead to financial crises. Given the pivotal role
played by CRAs in financial markets, it is of vital importance to develop
a framework that provides CRAs with optimal incentives to issue accu-
rate ratings. In this article, we attempt exactly this task.
Unsurprisingly, on both sides of the Atlantic, the regulatory reaction
to the global financial crisis also focused on rating agencies.
4
Legislators
have tried simultaneously to police the CRAs’ conflicts of interest
through regulation and to make them more accountable for their mis-
takes, overcoming the traditional insensitivity of CRAs to the threat of
of bonds that are issued by corporations, U.S. state and local governments, ‘sovereign’ gov-
ernment issuers of bonds abroad, and (most recently) mortgage securitizers.”).
2
See Reinier H. Kraakman, Gatekeepers: the Anatomy of a Third-Party Enforcement Strategy,2J.
L. ECON.&ORG. 53, 54 (1986); Gregory Husisian, What Standard of Care Should Apply to the
World’s Shortest Editorials? An Analysis of Bond Rating Agency Liability,75C
ORNELL L. REV.
411, 421 (1990) (arguing that rating agencies add value because they analyze issues less
expensively than the average investor); Susan M. Phillips & Alan N. Rechtschaffen, Interna-
tional Banking Activities: The Role of the Federal Reserve Bank in Domestic Capital Markets,21
FORDHAM INTLL.J. 1754, 1762–63 (1998) (“Finally, credit rating agencies enhance the capi-
tal markets infrastructure by distilling a great deal of information into a single credit rating
for a security. That rating reflects the informed judgment of the agency regarding the issu-
er’s ability to meet the terms of the obligation. Such information is frequently critical to
potential investors and could not be acquired otherwise, except at substantial cost.”).
3
See John C. Coffee, Jr., Ratings Reforms: The Good, The Bad and the Ugly,1HARV.BUS.L.
REV. 231, 261 (2011) (“Some believe that the basic error made by regulators was to grant
ratings agencies a de facto regulatory role. In truth, this decision, which dates back to the
1930s in the United States, was the product of the inability of financial regulators to define
excessive risk themselves.”).
4
For an overall comparative analysis of the regulatory approaches towards CRAs in the
European Union and in the United States, see generally ALINE DARBELLAY,REGULATING
CREDIT RATING AGENCIES (2013).
674 Vol. 52 / American Business Law Journal
liability.
5
In this vein, different from the past, some recent attempts to
impose liability on rating agencies have been successful. Australian
courts found Standard & Poor’s liable for misleading investors on struc-
tured finance products rated triple-A.
6
And in the United States,
Standard & Poor’s ultimately settled for payment of $1.5 million in the
lawsuit brought against them by the U.S. Department of Justice and a
few other states.
7
Only time will tell whether these outcomes can be generalized.
Undoubtedly, however, CRAs face today an increased liability threat
and more regulatory constraints on their operation.
8
The desirability
5
Before the Dodd- Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010, Pub.
L. No. 111-203, 124 Stat. 1376 (2010) [hereinafter Dodd-Frank Act], CRAs were largely
immune to liability in the United States. See Frank Partnoy, How and Why Credit Rating
Agencies Are Not Like Other Gatekeepers,in FINANCIAL GATEKEEPERS:CAN THEY PROTECT INVEST-
ORS? 61 (Yasuyuki Fuchita & Robert E. Litan eds., 2006). See also JOHN C. COFFEE,JR.,
GATEKEEPERS:THE PROFESSIONS AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 302 (2006) (emphasizing that
CRAs had enjoyed de facto immunity to liability). CRAs were immune to legal liability for
various reasons. For one, some U.S. courts placed ratings under the umbrella of the first
amendment. See Jefferson Cty. Sch. Dist. No. R-1 v. Moody’s Investor’s Serv., Inc., 175
F.3d 848, 852–56 (10th Cir. 1999); In re Enron Corp. Sec. Derivative & ERISA Litig. 511
F. Supp. 2d 742, 819–27 (S.D. Tex. 2005) (analyzing case law addressing first amendment
protection). For arguments against these decisions, see Caleb Deats, Note, Talk That Isn’t
Cheap: Does The First Amendment Protect Credit Rating Agencies’ Faulty Methodologies From Regu-
lation?, 110 COLUM.L.REV. 1818, 1818 (2010). Along similar lines, it was practically impos-
sible to sue CRAs for fraud under Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) Rule 10b-5
until the pleading standard—particularly regarding the showing of scienter—was lowered
by section 933 of the Dodd-Frank Act. See Coffee, supra note 3, at 267–68. Finally, SEC
Rule 436(g) exempted CRAs from liability as experts under section 11 of the Securities Act
of 1933. Adoption of Integrated Disclosure System, 47 Fed. Reg. 11,380, 11,391 (Mar. 18,
1982). Rule 436(g) was abolished by section 939G of the Dodd-Frank Act, supra.
6
ABN AMRO Bank NV v Bathurst Regional Council [2014] FCAFC 65 (Austl.) (confirming
the decision by the court of first instance to hold Standard & Poor’s liable for negligently
deceiving investors through inflated ratings).
7
See Aruna Viswanatha & Karen Freifeld, S&P reaches $1.5 Billion Deal With U.S., States over
Crisis-era Ratings, REUTERS (Feb. 3, 2015, 1:46 PM), http://www.reuters.com/article/2015/02/
03/us-s-p-settlement-idUSKBN0L71C120150203. Interestingly, the Department of Justice
decided to bring suit against S&P’s based on the private cause of action of a long-standing
statute, the Financial Institutions Reform, Recovery and Enforcement Act of 1989 (FIR-
REA), Pub. L. No. 101-73, 103 Stat. 183 (1989). Under FIRREA, the plaintiff needs to
establish its claim under a preponderance of evidence standard avoiding the more
demanding requirements of criminal law enforcement.
8
For example, among other things, the Dodd-Frank Act creates the “Office of Credit Rat-
ing” to monitor and control CRAs behavior. Dodd-Frank Act, supra note 5, § 939C. Also,
2015 / Strict Liability for Rating Agencies 675

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT