Strategic design under uncertain evaluations: structural analysis of design‐build auctions

Published date01 September 2018
Date01 September 2018
AuthorHidenori Takahashi
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12246
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.49, No. 3, Fall 2018
pp. 594–618
Strategic design under uncertain evaluations:
structural analysis of design-build auctions
Hidenori Takahashi
I investigate firms’ competition overprice and product design under uncertain design evaluations
in the context of Design-Build (DB) auctions. Reviewers’ design evaluations contain uncertainty
from a bidder’s perspective, leading luck to dampen differences in the firms’ chances of win-
ning. I model bidders’ behavior and show semiparametric identification of the model primitives.
Uncertain design evaluations increase the expected price of design quality and exacerbate an
auctioneer’s uncertainty in auction outcomes. These effects are mostly due to changes in bidding
strategies. Bid ranking swaps due to uncertain evaluations account for a small share of these
effects.
1. Introduction
Design competitions are widespread, ranging from grant applications in academic research
to the public design procurement of military weapons.1The outcomes of such design competitions
are, however, susceptible to a client’s subjective evaluation.Uncertain design evaluations introduce
an element of luck into design competitions: reducing the differences in the chances of winning
across designs of differing qualities.
I study the effect of a client’s uncertain evaluation on the suppliers’ design choices under
strategic interactions. A subjectivedesign evaluation may influence competition outcomes through
luck, which in turn affects the competing suppliers’ incentive to providea quality design. Despite
the fact that subjective evaluations are the norm in design competitions, their effect on suppliers’
behavior and competition outcomes are to date unknown.
To study suppliers’ behavior, I use hand-collected data on Design-Build (DB) auctions
from the Florida Department of Transportation (FDOT). DB auctions are used not only by state
University of Mannheim; htakahas@mail.uni-mannheim.de.
This article is based on Chapter 1 of my dissertation, completed in the Department of Economics at University of Toronto.
I am indebted to Victor Aguirregabiria for invaluable advice and generous guidance. I would also like to thank Andre
Boik, Ettore Damiano, Francesco Decarolis, Isis Durrmeyer, Rahul Deb, Serafin J. Grundl, Takakazu Honryo, Yao Luo,
Robert McMillan, Xianwen Shi, Michelle Sovinsky,Junichi Suzuki, Yuya Takahashi, Naoki Wakamori, Yuanyuan Wan,
and the participants in CEPR/JIE (Bologna, 2013), EARIE (´
Evora, 2013), and Jornadas de Econom´
ıa Industrial (Segovia,
2013) for helpful comments. Thanks to Daniel Garcia and Andrea Pozzi for extensivediscussions. Suggestions made by
the Editor and two anonymous referees significantly improvedthe article. All errors are my own.
1Public Private Partnerships, which havesurged in popularity among practitioners, are also an example of public
procurement that involves a design competition among consulting firms.
594 C2018, The RAND Corporation.
TAKAHASHI / 595
departments of transportation in the United States, but also in many other countries.2The US
Department of Defense extensively uses DB auctions to procure military construction projects
and military weapons, which together cost taxpayers billions of dollars annually.3
In a DB auction, bidders compete over price and design to win a contract to deliver an
infrastructure project, ranging from bridge repairs to building construction. Upon receiving price
and design proposals, each reviewer of the FDOTindependently evaluates and assigns a score to
every design proposal. The average across the reviewers’ evaluations then determines the quality
score of a design proposal. The bidder with the lowest price per quality score ratio (PQR) wins
the project and receives its price bid upon completing the project.4
The data reveal a substantial degree of discrepancy among reviewers for a given design
proposal, and conversations with contractors confirm that uncertain design evaluations are of
significant concern to them. Such uncertainty in design evaluations, which I refer to as evaluation
uncertainty, has not been considered to date in the vast auction literature. Indeed, to the best
of my knowledge, there is virtually no empirical work that has investigated the implications of
uncertain design evaluations on supplier behavior.
To guide the analysis, I develop a model in which each bidder strategically chooses its price
and design quality in the face of uncertain design evaluations. The model allows for complex
bidding strategies through multidimensional types: bidders are heterogeneous in the variable cost
of providing a quality design and in the fixed cost of implementing the designed project. The
introduction of a nonlinear quality cost function also allows for a flexible substitution pattern
between price and design quality choices.
A large degree of uncertainty in design evaluation implies that project allocation is heavily
influenced by luck. The effect of luck on project allocation is especially pronounced when com-
peting designs are comparable in quality. These designs are perfectly ranked without evaluation
noise but face an equal chance of winning with an infinite amount of evaluation uncertainty. I
find that the reduction in the differences in the bidders’ chances of winning results in: (i) a higher
expected price per unit of design quality; and (ii) a greater spread in price and design quality.That
is, greater evaluation uncertainty worsens the expected price of design quality, and exacerbates
the uncertainty in auction outcomes from the auctioneer’s point of view.
Identification of the model is challenging. The econometrician does not observe bidders’
design quality choices but instead observes some noisy evaluations of designs, implying that the
distribution of bidders’ costs needs to be identified separately from the distribution of noisy quality
signals. The problem of unobserved quality choices is further complicated by the endogeneity of
design quality choices. As the bidders’ design quality choices depend on the bidders’ unobserved
costs of producing quality designs, the identification of the quality cost function requires some
cost-irrelevant variable.
Unobserved heterogeneities further exacerbate the identification problem. Procurement auc-
tions of infrastructure projects are known to contain a significant degree of unobserved auc-
tion heterogeneity: the cost commonly shared and observed by bidders but unobserved by the
econometrician. Ignoring unobserved auction heterogeneity exaggerates the extent of bidder
heterogeneities, which in turn undermines the effect of uncertain design evaluations on bidding
incentives.The deg ree of evaluationuncertainty could also be confounded by unobserved reviewer
2As of October 2010, there are 39 state departments of transportation that use DB, including California, Delaware,
Georgia, and Minnesota. DB auctions are also common in other developed countries, including Canada, Italy, Japan, and
Sweden.
3The National Defense Authorization Act for the Fiscal Year 2015 (NDAA) bill, which became public law
in December 2014, explicitly prohibits the use of price-only auctions to procure construction services for military
construction contracts. The Associated General Contractors of America, which consists of 26,000 construction firms,
expresses its support to ban the use of price-only auctions for construction services for the reason that price-only auctions
ignore many aspects of design quality.
4PQR is a winner selection rule used by many state departments of transportation, including Alaska, Michigan,
North Carolina, and South Dakota.
C
The RAND Corporation 2018.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT