Strategic budgets in sequential elimination contests

AuthorGagan Ghosh,Steven Stong
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12292
Date01 August 2018
Published date01 August 2018
Received: 1 September 2017 Accepted: 16 February2018
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12292
ARTICLE
Strategic budgets in sequential elimination
contests
Gagan Ghosh1Steven Stong2
1CaliforniaState University Fullerton
2Universityof Iowa
GaganGhosh, Department of Economics, Mihaylo
Collegeof Business and Economics, California
StateUniversity Fullerton, 800 N. State College,
Blvd.SGMH-3313, Fullerton, CA 92834, USA
(gghosh@fullerton.edu).
StevenStong, Department of Economics, Univer-
sityof Iowa, 312 W PBB, Iowa City, IA 52246, USA
(ststong1.0@gmail.com).
We study a sequential elimination contest where contestants (e.g.,
campaigns) spend resources that are provided by strategic players
called backers (e.g., donors). In the unique symmetric equilibrium,
backersinitially provide small budgets, increasing their contributions
only if their contestant wins the preliminary round. If backers are
only allowed to provide budgets at the start of the game, as opposed
to before each round, spending is higher. When unspent resources
are refunded to the backer, total spending is higher than when all
resources are sunk costs. We also study an extension of the model
with asymmetric players.
1INTRODUCTION
Beginning with the seminal contribution of Tullock(1980), contests are often used to model competitions where play-
ers spend resources in order to win prizes. This framework is also used to model games such as tournaments where
players haveto compete with others sequentially, with the winner moving on to the next round. Such tournaments are
called elimination contests with a leading examplebeing political contests that take place over multiple rounds. In most
political competitions, from council elections at local municipalities to presidential elections, candidates have to win in
preliminary stages to enter a final race. In any political competition, campaigns compete with each other by spending
resources to increase their chances of winning. In many cases, the campaigns are funded by donors who are interested
in their candidate winning, but who also care about how much they spend. This suggests that there are strategic inter-
actions that take place between donors and campaigns as well as between rival donors and rival campaigns during
sequential contests. In this paper, our aim is to investigatesome of these interactions that play out through campaign
contributions.
To capture these interactions, we developa model of sequential elimination contests with the following feature:
campaigns control the timing and amount of spending while they depend on donors to providethe funds. By separating
spendingdecisions from financing ones, ouraim is to investigate the strategic nature of contributions. We believe this is
important, as donors are not passiveplayers and thus choose their contributions strategically, both in terms of amounts
andtiming. Therefore, modeling fundsreceived by campaigns as endogenous objects, as opposed to an exogenous ones,
couldhelp us to understand the reasons behind certain patterns of campaign donations, such as timing of contributions.
Furthermore, from a policy standpoint, this model allows us to study the effect of campaign finance rules on donors, as
they will react strategically to anypolicy change in the model.
Specifically,we focus on an elimination contest with two groups of contestants. The preliminary contests are within
groups. The winners of each preliminary round compete for a prize in a final round. Contestants in the elimination
Journal of Public Economic Theory.2018;20:499–524. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet c
2018 Wiley Periodicals,Inc. 499
500 GHOSH AND STONG
contest depend on a set of strategic players, called backers, to provide the resources that will be spent in the con-
test. Each contestant's objective is to spend resources to maximize the probability of winning the final contest taking
into account the other players'strategies.Contestants'spending is constrained by the resources they receive. Backers
would like to increase the chance of their contestant winning, but the probability of winning is weighed against the
cost of providing resources. This formulation highlights the different incentives to spendof the two sets of players. We
derive the unique symmetric equilibrium of such a model under a variety of spending rules (Propositions 2.1 and 2.2).
We show that backers'spending is lower when they can provide funds at different stages of the game, as opposed
to providing everything up front (Section 2.4). Therefore, backers prefer to give contributions in a piecemeal fashion,
as opposed to all at once. This is in line with the empirical observation that candidates typically raise more money in
the general election than in the primaries. This result also provides us with a policy proposal. Spending will be lower if
a sufficient amount of time is provided between stages for contestants to raise more donations.
Wealso study the effect of a rule governing how unspent resources are used. Unspent budgets can occur in the elim-
ination contest when a contestant loses the preliminary contest and has some budget remaining. In political contests,
the way unspent campaign funds are used after the campaign is often regulated. Although donations can be returned
to donors, more often theyare spent in a way that is an imperfect substitute for a refund. For example, the funds may be
donated to a charity,another campaign, or a political party. We show that in an elimination contest in which resources
are only provided at the beginning of the game, spending increases with the fraction of unspent resources that are
returned to backers.1
Finally, we carry out an extensionof the baseline mode to include the possibility of asymmetric players. We do so
by including an incumbent in the model, who is assumed to be uncontested in the preliminary round. We also allow the
incumbent to havedifferent valuations than the other players called challengers. We compare rent dissipation and costs
between the baseline model and the extension and show that some of the results reverse. In our framework, we also
show that an incumbent is more likely to win the final round conditional on not being too weak, that is, not having too
low a valuation compared to the challengers.
This feature of the equilibrium suggests that strategic behavior of donors could be one of the sources of the incum-
bency advantage, an empirical observation that essentially states that incumbents tend to win more often.2Levitt and
Wolfram(1997) show that the ability of incumbents to deter high-quality challengers seems to account for increases in
incumbency advantage for U.S. House races from 1948 to 1990. This is precisely what occurs in our framework: even
moderately weak incumbents havea higher likelihood of winning against strong challengers. In the model, challengers
have inadequate time to raise funds between the primary and general election. Due to this, the challenger's backers
haveto commit to contribution levels before the preliminary round. In contrast, the incumbent's backercan react opti-
mally to the budget the challenger brings to the final round, giving her an advantage. This depresses the contribution
levelsfor the challengers and allows even moderately weak incumbents to have an advantage over strong challengers.3
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In the next subsection, we discuss our paper in the context of related
works. We present the model in Section 2. In Sections 2.1 and 2.3, we discuss the unique equilibrium of the model
under two different spending rules and the associated costs and rents. In Section 3, we introduce a variation to the
baseline model where we allow players to be asymmetric. Section 4 concludes the article. All proofs are presented in
the appendix.
1.1 Previous literature
Sequential elimination contest models are a natural extension of their one shot contest counterparts and have been
studied as far back as Rosen (1986) in the context of labor promotions and sport tournaments. His work grew
1Ifthe backers are allowed to provide resources at each stage, there are no unspent resources in equilibrium.
2SeeGelman and King (1990), Cox and Katz (1996), and Ansolabehere and Snyder (2002).
3Being an incumbent is not always an advantage. We establish conditions under which a (very)weak incumbent faces a disadvantage in equilibrium. Under
someconditions, the incumbent is completely deterred from competing.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT