Strapping Down Regulatory Space With Investment Arbitration: a New Breed of International Slapps

STRAPPING DOWN REGULATORY SPACE WITH
INVESTMENT ARBITRATION: A NEW BREED OF
INTERNATIONAL SLAPPS
DAVID CHRIKI*
ABSTRACT
Litigation cost asymmetries among governments and investors could hinder
the ability of governments to exercise their legitimate rights to regulate and
enforce their laws. A foreign investor facing government measures that
adversely affect the investor’s business interests might submit an arbitration
claim, arguing that the host country violated provisions of an international
investment agreement (IIA). If the investor enjoys litigation cost advantages
over the host country, that country will be inclined to settle regardless of the mer-
its of the claim. Investors, realizing that they enjoy such cost advantages, could
choose to weaponize their right to arbitration and bargain over the contested
measure in the shadow of investment arbitration. In these cases, investment
arbitration imposes an unwarranted regulatory chill on countries, which
exceeds the substantial obligations derived from their IIAs. These arbitration
claims, referred to here as Strategic Arbitrations Against Public Policies
(STRAPPs), resemble so-called “SLAPPs”—Strategic Lawsuits Against Public
Participation—which are usually f‌iled by large corporations against social acti-
vists who call for regulations that adversely affect the corporations’ interests.
The use of international investment arbitration to “STRAPP down” various
measures is examined here in three different contexts: criminal investigations;
health policies against tobacco products; and tax and antitrust policies.
Drawing from the experience with SLAPPs, the deleterious effects of STRAPPs
could be avoided by dismissing arbitration claims against well-def‌ined types of
measures unless the claimant can show evidence of damages and arbitrary or
discriminatory treatment, while awarding governments punitive damages
caused by the arbitration in such cases.
I. INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 416
II. INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT ARBITRATION AND ITS POSSIBLE
IMPLICATIONS ON GOVERNMENTS’ REGULATORY SPACE . . . . . . . . . 422
* LL.B, LL.M, Hebrew University of Jerusalem. I am grateful to Ari Af‌ilalo, Tomer Broude,
Alex Stein, Ifat Taraboulos, Nir Deuitch, Katya Zakharov-Assaf and Ari Pomson for their valuable
comments. This research enjoyed the kind support of the Feinberg Fund for International Law at
the Law Faculty of the Hebrew University of Jerusalem. V
C 2020, David Chriki.
415
III. WEAPONIZING THE RIGHT TO ARBITRATION: THEORETICAL
FRAMEWORK AND EXAMPLES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 425
IV. EVIDENCE OF STRAPPS: A NEW BREED OF INTERNATIONAL
SLAPPS. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 429
A. Avoiding Criminal Proceedings: The Case of Foreign Bribery. 431
B. Health Regulations: Investment Arbitration Against Tobacco
Packaging. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 434
C. Tax and Antitrust Regulations: Noble Energy and the
Regulatory Framework of Natural Resources in Israel . . . . . . 439
V. PROPOSED SOLUTIONS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 441
A. Preventing SLAPPs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 442
B. Anti-SLAPP Solutions as Possible Mechanisms for Preventing
STRAPPs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 443
VI. CONCLUSION. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 447
I. INTRODUCTION
Investment arbitration could be used to deter countries from exer-
cising their regulatory powers, even when they are entitled to do in
accordance with their obligations under international investment
law. Once foreign investors face measures that adversely affect their
business interests, they might submit arbitration claims against the
country they invested in, arguing that the measures violated one or
more provisions of an international investment agreement (IIA)
between the regulating country and the respective countries of the
investors. Notably, in many of these cases, the likelihood that the in-
vestor will prevail in arbitration is not high. However, I contend that
governments are likely to settle, and cancel or alter the contested
measure if the litigation costs they face are higher than those of the
threatening investor, regardless of the scope of protection provided
to investors in the countries’ IIAs and of the countries’ likelihood of
prevailing in arbitration.
1
When an investor enjoys a cost advantage compared to the respond-
ent country, that investor might “weaponize” its right to arbitration and
cause the respondent country to cancel challenged measures, even if
1. See generally Gideon Parchomovsky & Alex Stein, The Relational Contingency of Rights, 98 VA. L.
REV. 1313 (2012) (arguing that “whether a right — indeed, any legal entitlement — is realizable
will always critically depend on the relationship between two variables: [1] the cost a rightsholder
would need to incur to vindicate the right; and [2] the cost faced by a challenger who wishes to
attack and ultimately eliminate the right”).
GEORGETOWN JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONAL LAW
416 [Vol. 51
the IIA does not provide the investor protection from such measures.
2
These arbitration claims, referred to here as Strategic Arbitrations
against Public Policies (STRAPPs), raise concerns that investment arbi-
tration imposes an unwarranted regulatory chill on countries which
extends beyond the scope of the substantial obligations derived from
their IIAs.
Consider the following hypothetical example. GoldCo, a Ruritania-
based mining company, obtained mining concessions in a gold mine in
Utopia, an emerging country with only one gold mine which is
expected to increase the country’s revenues. It came to light that
GoldCo had obtained its mining rights by bribing Utopian government
off‌icials. The Utopian government withdraws GoldCo’s mining license
and prosecutes GoldCo’s off‌icials. In response, GoldCo submits an arbi-
tration claim against Utopia based on the investment-state dispute set-
tlement (ISDS) provision in the IIA concluded between Utopia and
Ruritania. GoldCo argues that Utopia initiated arbitrary measures
against it, and thereby unlawfully expropriated GoldCo’s mining rights
and violated Utopia’s obligation to provide foreign investors fair and
equitable treatment. Utopia has a strong case against GoldCo off‌icials,
and is conf‌ident it will prevail in arbitration. However, it soon realizes
that litigation costs are onerous: legal fees could reach millions of dol-
lars; the gold mine would be left undeveloped during the course of the
legal proceedings; and other foreign investors would quickly become
uneasy about the reliability of law enforcement authorities in Utopia,
and then refrain from investing in the country. In contrast, GoldCo’s
legal fees would be somewhat lower than those of Utopia, and it would
not bear any other litigation costs. Under such circumstances, if
Utopian off‌icials value the economic advantages of developing the gold
mine more than they do the rule of law, they will be inclined to settle
with GoldCo and drop the bribery allegations in order to avoid litiga-
tion costs and facilitate the development of the gold mine.
This example demonstrates that when a threatened government esti-
mates that litigation costs will exceed the value it attaches to its right to
carry out the challenged measure, it would be inclined to settle and
avoid these litigation costs, regardless of its anticipated chances of
2. Brad A. Greenberg, Copyright Trolls and Presumptively Fair Uses, 85 U. COLO. L. REV. 53, 84
(2014) (demonstrating how “copyright trolls” who enjoy legal cost advantages weaponize their
copyrights against infringers “[e]ven if the infringer has a strong fair use defense”); see also David
Orozco, Strategic Legal Bullying, 13 N.Y.U. J.L. & BUS. 137, 143 (2016) (examining methods of
“strategic legal bullying” which “asserts or frivolously defends a baseless legal position to derive
advantage by exploiting the high cost of the legal system as a barrier to seeking a remedy”).
A NEW BREED OF INTERNATIONAL SLAPPS
2020] 417

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT