State‐owned firms and private debt

Published date01 October 2018
AuthorPierre M. Picard,Ridwan D. Rusli
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12297
Date01 October 2018
P
672 © 2018 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet Journal of Public Economic Theory. 2018;20:672702.
Received:12 May2017 Accepted:18 March 2018
DOI:10.1111/jpet.12297
ARTICLE
State-owned firms and private debt
Pierre M. Picard1Ridwan D. Rusli2
1Universityof Luxembourg, Luxembourg, and
CORE,Université Catholique de Louvain
2TechnischeHochschule Köln, Cologne, Ger-
many,and CREA, University of Luxembourg,
Luxembourg
PierreM. Picard, CREA, University of Luxem-
bourg,Luxembourg, and CORE, Université
Catholiquede Louvain, Louvain-la-Neuve, Bel-
gium(pierre.picard@uni.lu).
RidwanD. Rusli, TechnischeHochschule Köln,
Cologne,Germany, and CREA, University of
Luxembourg,Luxembourg (ridwan.rusli@th-
koeln.de ).
We study the role of private debt financing in reducing government
transfers and information costs in a state-owned firm. We show
that debt contracts allow the government to reduce socially costly
subsidies by letting underperforming state-owned firms default.
When the firm has private information, the government uses debt to
reducethe firm's information rents. The option of default and privati-
zation allows the government to stop subsidizing the firm. We iden-
tify the conditions under which information costs outweigh privati-
zation costs and a positive debt levelbenefits governments.
1INTRODUCTION
In most developed and less developed countries, a nonnegligible set of enterprises produce and sell goods or ser-
vices with partial or full public financing, and under the control of a variety of governmental institutions. The United
States hosts government-sponsored corporations, federallyowned corporations, and quasi-governmental agencies in
which governmental involvement is formalized (e.g., United States Postal Service, Tenessee Valley Authority). More
than 1,000 public hospitals are funded and controlled by state and local governments. Canada hosts para-publicorga-
nizations such as universities and Hydro-Québec. Francehas its “public establishments for industrial and commercial
purpose” (EPIC) that manage metro and train infrastructures,opera, and others. Less transparent are some for-profit
firms that nevertheless remain under the government'scontrol. For instance, Amtrak has all “preferred stocks” owned
by the U.S.Department of Transportation and its chief executiveofficer (CEO) appointed by the U.S. Congress. In China
and across the emerging world, manygovernment-linked corporations are effectively controlled by their governments,
even though theyare listed in the stock markets and financed with private equity and debt.
State-owned firms that are financed, owned, and controlled by the government are of major economic importance
in many countries. While such firms contributed between 6% and 8% of total gross domestic product (GDP) across
countries worldwide in the late nineties, public interventions in the last decade have led governmentsto own approxi-
mately one-fifth of global stock marketcapitalization (Megginson & Netter, 2001). A particular feature of state-owned
or state-controlled firms is that they hold significant levels of debt in the form of loans and bonds to the private sec-
tor,which reduce government equity injections. State-owned firms usually incur debt levels higher than a third of their
assets and are responsible for the issuance of many bonds worldwide. D'Souza and Megginson (1999) and Megginson,
Nash, and van Randenborgh (1994) observe that state-owned firms'average debt-to-asset ratio ranges from 29% to
66%, and that these ratios decreased after privatization. Borisova, Fotak, Holland, and Megginson (2012) describe no
less than 1,000 bonds issued by 215 listed state-owned firms across 43 countries in the last decade.
d
r
2
o
c
e
o
a
f
u
c
T
t
C
p
R
C
B
d
D
t
t
a
i
n
v
N
i
n
c
p
a
p
B
o
m
(
o
1
2
c
o
3
(
A
t
i
a
PICARD ANDRUSLI 3
673
2.
r
-
d
n
e
-
a
l
t
d
a
s
,
e
s
-
d
c
-
r
n
,
o
o
Debt leverage has become a concern for many governments and regulators. For example,the recent increase in
debt leverage among public and private firms operating in regulated markets has motivated Ofwat, the U.K. water
regulator,to introduce restrictions on companies operating with high debt levels (Correia da Silva, Estache, & Jarvela,
2006;National Audit Office, 2015). Similarly,the high leverage of procurement projects has increased the probability
of financial distress and hence the frequency of renegotiation and recapitalization of publicprivate partnership (PPP)
contracts (Engel, Fischer,& Galetovic, 2010;Klein, 2012;Moore, Straub, & Dieter, 2014;Yescombe,2011).
The use of external debt bystate-owned companies is striking for two reasons. On the one hand, governments gen-
erally access credit marketsat better conditions than private agents. Because governments hold diversified portfolios
ofpublic projects, have recourse to taxation, and face no bankruptcy risk, government bonds are considered as risk-free
and offer the lowest interest rates in most modern economies. As a consequence, public projects should be internally
funded from the treasury rather than externally with private creditors. On the other hand, the use of external debt
contracts introduces the possibility of bankruptcy when state-owned firms are unable to meet their debt obligations.
The government must then face the difficult decision of whether to refinance and bail out state-owned firms, or to let
them default and relinquish control to private creditors.
A number of state-owned firms haveindeed defaulted in the past and are still undergoing default procedures today.
Creditors acquired (temporary) control of defaulting firms during the Asian crisis in the late 1990s. Many European
public airline companies went bankrupt and/or were privatized in the past decades. Post companies like the U.K.
Royal Mail are set in the process of privatization because their debts became a subject of intense political concern. In
China, thousands of smaller Chinese central and regional state-owned companies have gone bankrupt overthe years.
Between 1975 and 2008, many financially distressed public hospitals in the United States were unable to service their
debts because of insufficient revenues resulting from excess capacity and increasing number of uninsured patients.
Due to deteriorating public finances, many local governments refused to inject new funds and decided to privatize
them (Ramamonjiarivelo et al., 2015).
Such cases of default and subsequent privatization of state-owned firms necessitate governments'commitment
to—immediately or eventually—stop subsidizing the firm and face the risk of operational disruption and employees'
and citizens'discontent.1These examples takeplace under crisis conditions and in complex multiyear processes, often
involving interim subsidies. Nevertheless, they highlight the fact that debt contracts maytrigger governments'disin-
vestment in nonperforming state-owned firms. In many instances, bankruptcy is not a necessary step for privatization.
Numerous money-losing state-owned enterprises have placed themselvesunder pressure of their creditors before fil-
ing for bankruptcy. They have been privatized and sold to consortia of private investorswho often included former
creditors. Hence, the broader question that we explore in this paper is whether the debt policy and the subsequent
pressure from creditors can be used by governments as instruments to discipline state-owned firms'managements.
The objectiveof this paper is to highlight the role of debt leverage when state-owned firms benefit from information
advantages. We show that the governmenthas incentives to induce the state-owned firms to take a debt contract with
private creditors because the possibility of not bailing out the firm reduces information rents.2
Tohighlight this mechanism, we revisit the natural monopoly regulation setup with adverse selection presented in
Baron and Myerson (1982) and Laffont and Tirole (1993). A utilitarian and benevolent government monitors a state-
owned firm operating in a natural monopoly market,such as transport, water, energy, waste, and health.3The govern-
ment faces an information asymmetry because the firm's management has private knowledge about the firm's cost
(or demand parameter). The government faces a budget constraint that is summarized by its “shadow” cost of public
1Inthis paper, we define liquidation as the government's act of defaulting and subsequently privatizing the state-owned firm to private creditors or investors.
2Default provisionsof typical loan agreements and bond prospectuses often exclude government guarantee clauses;they thus convey an implicit no-bailout
commitment.
3Many state-owned companies are local natural monopolies like in water supply in poor countries and hospital care in sparsely populated rural America
(Alexander,D'Aunno, & Succi, 1996;Auriol & Blanc, 2009;Langabeer, 2006). Before 2002, EU national airlines could benefit from an artificial monopoly posi-
tion under countries'air transportbilateral agreements. Our analysis of monopoly can be generalized to oligopolistic markets as in Auriol and Laffont (1992)
andAuriol and Picard (2008).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT