State Eyes on the Climate Policy Prize

AuthorRobert N. Stavins
PositionAlbert Pratt Professor of Business and Government at the John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, and Director of the Harvard Environmental Economics Program
Pages16-16
Page 16 THE ENVIRONMENTAL FORUM Copyright © 2010, Environmental Law Institute®, Washington, D.C. www.eli.org.
Reprinted by permission from The Environmental Forum®, July/August 2010
By Robert N. Stavins
State Eyes on the
Climate Policy Prize
In May, Senators John Kerry and Joe
Lieberman released their American
Power Act of 2010, legislative compan-
ion to Representatives Henry Waxman
and Edward Markeys American Clean
Energy and Security Act of 2009.
Both proposals feature cap-and-trade
systems at their heart, and constitute
the best remaining shot at addressing
climate change in the near future. But
there’s an issue brewing that could un-
dermine their ef‌fectiveness and drive
up their costs.
Government of‌f‌icials from Cali-
fornia, New York, and other states are
lobbying in Washington to retain their
existing state and regional systems for
reducing greenhouse gas emissions,
even after a federal system comes into
force. at would be a mistake — and
a potentially expensive one for resi-
dents of those states, who could wind
up subsidizing the rest of the country.
National climate legislation should
preempt state and regional cap-and-
trade systems. eres no risk, because
if federal legislation is not enacted, such
preemption will not take ef‌fect.
e regional systems — including
the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initia-
tive in the Northeast and Assembly
Bill 32 in California seek to limit
carbon dioxide by making emissions
more costly for f‌irms and individuals.
ese systems were developed because
the federal government was not mov-
ing fast enough.
ough the Congress has typically
allowed states to act more aggressively
on environmental protection, this
makes no sense when it comes to cli-
mate change policy. For other, localized
environmental problems, California or
Massachusetts may wish to incur the
costs of achieving cleaner air or water
within their borders than required by
a national threshold. But with climate
change, it is impossible for regions,
states, or localities to achieve great-
er protection for their jurisdictions
through more ambitious actions.
is is because greenhouse gases
uniformly mix in the atmosphere — a
unit of carbon dioxide emitted in Cali-
fornia contributes just as much to the
problem as carbon dioxide emitted in
Tennessee. e overall magnitude of
damages — and their location — are
completely unaf‌fected by the location
of emissions. is means that for any
individual jurisdiction,
the benef‌its of action
will inevitably be less
than the costs. (is is
the same reason why
U.S. federal action on
climate change should
occur at the same time
as other countries take actions to re-
duce their emissions).
If federal climate policy comes into
force, the more stringent California
policy will accomplish no additional
reductions in greenhouse gases, but
simply increase the state’s costs and
subsidize other parts of the country.
is is because under a nationwide
cap-and-trade system, any additional
emission reductions achieved in Cali-
fornia will be of‌fset by fewer reductions
in other states.
A national cap-and-trade system
which is needed to address emissions
meaningfully and cost-ef‌fectively —
will undo the ef‌fects of a more strin-
gent cap within any state or group of
states. RGGI, which covers only elec-
tricity generation and which will be less
stringent than the federal policy, will
be irrelevant once the federal system
comes into force.
In principle, a new federal policy
could allow states to opt out if they im-
plement a program at least as stringent.
But why should states want to opt out?
High-cost states will be better of‌f join-
ing the national system to lower their
costs. And states that can reduce emis-
sions more cheaply will be net sellers of
federal allowances.
is is certainly not to say that there
is no possible role for state and local
policies. Price signals provided by a na-
tional cap-and-trade system are neces-
sary to address climate change at sen-
sible cost, but other market failures call
for supplementary policies. Take, for
example, the principal-agent problem
through which despite higher energy
prices, both landlords and tenants lack
incentives to make economically ef‌f‌i-
cient energy-conservation investments,
such as installing insulation. is prob-
lem can be handled by state and local
authorities through regionally dif‌fer-
entiated building codes
and zoning.
But for the core of
climate policy — which
is carbon pricing
the simplest, cleanest,
and best way to avoid
unnecessary costs and
unnecessary actions is for existing
state systems to become part of the
federal system. Political leaders across
the country would do well to follow
the progressive lead of Massachusetts
Governor Deval Patrick, who has pub-
licly supported RGGI preemption by a
meaningful national program.
Californias leaders and those in the
Northeast may take great pride in their
state and regional climate policies, but
if they accomplish their frequently-
stated goal — helping to bring about
the enactment of a meaningful national
climate policy — they will better serve
their states and the country by declar-
ing victory and getting out of the way.
Federal legislation
should preempt state
and regional cap-
and-trade systems
Ro ber t N . St avi ns is the Albert Pratt Profes-
sor of Business and Government at the John
F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvar d
University, and Dir ector of the Har vard En -
vironmental Economics Program. He can b e
reached at rob ert_stavins@har vard.edu.
A E P

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT