Spatial Interdependence in US Outward FDI into Africa, Latin America and the Caribbean

Published date01 September 2014
AuthorUwaoma G. Nwaogu,Michael Ryan
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12118
Date01 September 2014
Spatial Interdependence in US Outward
FDI into Africa, Latin America and the
Caribbean
Uwaoma G. Nwaogu
1
and Michael Ryan
2
1
Economics, Accounting and Management, Central College, Pella, IA, USA and
2
Department of
Economics, Western Michigan University, Kalamazoo, MI, USA
1. INTRODUCTION
THIS paper extends the previous literature on spatial interdependence and foreign direct
investment (FDI) by examining US outbound FDI into Africa, Latin America and the
Caribbean (LAC). We empirically examine the questions of whether spatial interdependence
matters in these regions for US FDI, and what the prominent motivations are for this invest-
ment.
1
However, we do so with a much broader empirical question in mind: given that the
existing literature on spatial interdependence has primarily focused on developed economies
(with good infrastructure and historically strong/significant trade ties), do spatial linkages exist
between countries where these facts do not exist? In Africa and Latin America, where the
infrastructure lags behind developed hosts and trade ties are less prominent, spatial interde-
pendence may not matter for FDI. This paper explicitly tests these relationships.
The importance of spatial analysis in analysing FDI flows comes from the fact that proxim-
ity matters and what happens in a particular region is interrelated with what is happening in
neighbouring regions. Put differently, geographical units closer to each other ought to exhibit
a higher degree of spatial dependence than those distant from each other. As suggested by
Tobler (1970, p. 236), the First Law of Geography states: ‘Everything is related to everythin g
else, but near things are more related than distant things’. Although the bilatera l gravity
model simplifies the empirical analysis allowing researchers to focus on how certain host and
parent country characteristics interact to affect the host’s inward FDI, it ignores the role
played by neighbouring countries, otherwise known as third-country effects. Ignoring such
effects could pose several problems.
For instance, Blonigen et al. (2007) noted that the recent decade’s empirical work on FDI
determinants relies primarily on a bilateral gravity-type framework. However, from an econo-
metric perspective, third-country effects are important as their omission leads to biased, incon-
sistent or inefficient parameter estimates (Anselin, 1988). These third countries are usually
countries in the immediate proximity to the host country. Furthermore, bilateral FDI analysis
We would like to thank Paul Elhorst for his helpful comments and suggestions on the MATLAB coding.
We also thank our referee, Susan Pozo, Christine Moser, and Rajib Paul for their valuable comments on
the text.
1
Here we consider FDI ‘motivation’ to be vertical, horizontal, export-platform, or complex vertical
FDI. See subsection 2b for a discussion of each strategy. A mixture of FDI strategies might exist when
one uses country- and industry-level data; as a result, one cannot directly test for the existence of one
form of FDI over the other. However, as empirical analysis can capture net effects, Blonigen et al.
(2007, p. 1308) indicate ‘evidence of one dominant form of multinational enterprises activity in the data
is possible given unique sign patters across the various FDI forms’.
©2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 1267
The World Economy (2014)
doi: 10.1111/twec.12118
The World Economy
is problematic as it cannot explain newer FDI models such as export-platform FDI (Ekholm
et al., 2007) and complex vertical FDI (Baltagi et al., 2007; Kazunobu and Toshiyuki, 2011).
The use of spatial econometrics allows us to overcome these problems by capturing how the
dependent variable (FDI) for a given spatial unit is jointly determined with that of surround-
ing spatial units, weighted by their geographical distance. For instance, recent empirical mod-
els (Coughlin and Segev, 2000; Baltagi et al., 2007; Blonigen et al., 2007; Garretsen and
Peeters, 2009; Ledyaeva, 2009) have relaxed the two-country assumption by accounting for
spatial interdependence in a gravity framework. In particular, empirical analysis from Baltagi
et al. (2007) and Blonigen et al. (2007) confirm that after controlling for all the relevant loca-
tion determinants, multinational enterprises (MNEs) do take third-country effects into
consideration when deciding on where to do FDI.
If one were to look for a unifying theme among the aforementioned spatial FDI papers, it
would be that the destination countries/regions within each particular study are somewhat
homogeneous. For instance, 17 of Blonigen et al.’s (2007) 35 host countries are European,
2
suggesting strong geographical, infrastructure (rail, air, road) and social ties exist, binding
these countries together economically. In addition, by 2010, 24 are OECD members, with
non-OECD member Singapore ranking 26th in the UN’s Human Development Index.
3
We
also expect strong economic ties to exist between these hosts, even if they are not geographi-
cally close. In fact, the CIA Factbook highlights that in almost every case, the top export
destinations for the European countries in the Blonigen et al. (2007) study are other European
countries (see https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/fields/2050.html#
be). In essence, a high level of homogeneity exists among the hosts with regard to economic
development, social development, legal structure and geography. Garretsen and Peeters’
(2009) study is subject to the same concern, as it focuses on Dutch FDI into 18 countries, 14
of which are European (10 of 12 are European when they focus on FDI at the sectoral level).
Coughlin and Segev (2000) examine FDI into 29 Chinese regions and thus have a less
homogeneous set of recipient regions with respect to economic development. However, these
are a geographically unified set of host regions tied together under the Chinese federal
government (and thus use the same currency, legal system, etc.). In each of these cases, the
presence of several unifying ties between hosts would, a priori, reasonably suggest spatial
interdependence exists.
However, the question that naturally arises from this is what if we ‘relax’ some of these
homogeneities and economic ties among the recipient countries. To do so, we focus on US
FDI flows into Latin American/Caribbean (LAC) and Africa. While countries within these
regions share a similar continent, they are far more geographically dispersed than Europe,
which is 1/3 the area of Africa and 60 per cent the size of South America. In addition, we
have greater heterogeneity in our sample with regard to host economic and social develop-
ment. For instance, Blonigen et al.’s (2007) set of 35 countries average 0.822 on the 2011
UN Human Development Index (‘very high human development’), with a standard deviation
in this rank of 0.105. Garretsen and Peeters’s (2009) 18 hosts average 0.890 (0.029 standard
deviation) on this scale, indicating a much more homogeneous set of recipient countries.
In contrast, our set of countries, 68 countries, has an average index of 0.595, with a
2
18 counting Israel, typically considered be more economically aligned with Europe than its own
geographical region.
3
See http://hdr.undp.org/en/statistics/. Blonigen et al.’s (2007) sample of 35 host countries includes only
six countries from LAC and two from Africa.
©2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
1268 U. G. NWAOGU AND M. RYAN

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT