Sovereign Risk and Government Change: Elections, Ideology and Experience

AuthorSarah M. Brooks,Raphael Cunha,Layna Mosley
Published date01 August 2022
Date01 August 2022
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/00104140211047407
Subject MatterArticles
Article
Comparative Political Studies
2022, Vol. 55(9) 15011538
© The Author(s) 2022
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/00104140211047407
journals.sagepub.com/home/cps
Sovereign Risk and
Government Change:
Elections, Ideology and
Experience
Sarah M. Brooks
1
, Raphael Cunha
2
, and
Layna Mosley
3
Abstract
Global capital markets can react dramatically to elections in developing
countries, affecting governmentsaccess to f‌inance and sometimes setting off
broader crises. We argue, contrary to some conventional wisdom, that in-
vestors do not systematically react to the election of left-leaning parties and
candidates. Government ideology is often an imprecise heuristic, given the
diversity in policies among parties, especially those on the left. We therefore
expect that neither elections generally, nor elections that produce specif‌ic
partisan outcomes, are associated with signif‌icant changes in sovereign f‌i-
nancing costs. Yet we also predict that the election of left-leaning parties will
generate volatility in sovereign bond markets, ref‌lecting investorsuncertainty
over future policy outcomes. This volatility is especially pronounced when
new governments take off‌ice; over time, however, government policy per-
formance enables investors to make increasingly precise estimates of political
risk. Volatility has implications for the real economy, as well as for gov-
ernmentsability to manage their debt. We test, and f‌ind support for, our core
expectations using monthly data on sovereign bond spreads and credit default
swap prices for 74 developing countries from 19942015.
1
Ohio State University, Columbus, OH, USA
2
Florida State University, Tallahassee, FL, USA
3
Princeton University, Princeton, NJ, USA
Corresponding Author:
Sarah M. Brooks, Department of Political Science, Ohio State University, 2140 Derby Hall,
Columbus, OH 43210, USA.
Email: brooks.317@osu.edu
Keywords
political economy, presidents and executive politics, political parties,
globalization, sovereign debt
In an era of f‌inancial globalization, market responses to elections can dra-
matically affect governmentsf‌inancing capabilities, as well as the cost of
capital throughout the economy. Elections may generate uncertainty not only
about who will win, but also about which coalition will govern and which
policies the new government will adopt. In developing and advanced in-
dustrial nations alike, elections have generated foreign exchange speculation
(Bernhard and Leblang, 2006;Eichengreen et al., 1995;Leblang, 2002);
declines in sovereign credit ratings (Block and Vaaler, 2004;Vaaler et al.,
2006); increased spreads on sovereign debt (Mart´
ınez and Santiso, 2003;
Block and Vaaler, 2004;Vaaler et al., 2005); and stock market volatility
(Jensen and Schmith, 2005;Leblang and Mukherjee, 2005). Like broader
macroeconomic volatility and capital f‌light, volatility in government f‌inancing
costs can impose signif‌icant welfare costs on developing countries as gov-
ernment investment and spending are curbed, threatening growth as con-
sumption shocks reverberate through the economy (Loayza et al., 2007;
Pastor, 1990). Market reactions can be particularly notable when elections
result in partisan switches, perhaps implying signif‌icant policy changes
(Sattler, 2013). Left-leaning governments are more likely to defend their
currencies from speculative attacks, while right-leaning governments are
associated with looser bank regulation (Broz, 2013;Walter, 2009). Investors
in government bonds may worry that left governments will raise taxes, inf‌late
the economy or even default on sovereign debt. If these expectations generate
negative market reactions, newly elected governments may be tempted to
reverse their policies, sometimes dramatically.
Yet, even when elections result in partisan switches or victories for left-
leaning governments, they do not always generate negative market reactions.
Indeed, as we demonstrate below, most national elections in developing
countries are not associated with abnormal bond market returns. We therefore
offer a more nuanced assessment of the causal channels through which
elections affect investorsrisk assessments. We theorize that government
partisanship is not a consistently useful information shortcut for investors.
Rather, the partisan signal is noisy: there is signif‌icant macroeconomic policy
heterogeneity among left-leaning political parties. As a result, left-leaning
governments will not pay systematically higher borrowing costs than their
right-leaning counterparts.
At the same time, elections and partisan shifts do increase investors
uncertainty regarding future government policy, especially for newly elected
1502 Comparative Political Studies 55(9)
left-leaning governments. Uncertainty among investors regarding the course
of future policy generates greater volatility in sovereign bond pricing for
newly elected left governments. Volatility can have important consequences
for government debt management, as well as for broader economic outcomes.
As government time in off‌ice increases, investors are better able to form
expectations regarding future policies, and volatility decreases. We test our
claims using data from 74 emerging market countries between 1994 and 2015.
Our analyses, which support our core empirical predictions, further our
understanding of the precise linkages between domestic politics and inter-
national f‌inancial markets.
Markets, Elections and Political Risk
Investors in sovereign debt are closely attuned to default, as well as inf‌lation
and currency, risk (Eaton and Gersovitz, 1981;Eichengreen and Hausmann,
2005;Tomz and Wright, 2013). Although developing countriesaccess to
capital markets is driven partly by global and regional factors (Brooks et al.,
2015;Gray, 2013;Longstaff et al., 2011;Ballard-Rosa et al., 2021), country-
specif‌ic factors play a central role. When evaluating sovereign risk, investors
consider governmentsability, as well as their willingness, to pay. Ability to
pay typically is associated with macroeconomic fundamentals, including
public debt, current account position, and reserve holdings, as well as with
monetary and f‌iscal institutions (Bodea and Hicks, 2015,Mosley, 2003).
Investors also may reward f‌inancial and economic transparency (Copelovitch
et al., 2018). Willingness to pay, on the other,hand, usual ly is associated with
domestic political institutions. For instance, democratic regime structures may
encourage respect for loan contracts; constrain executive f‌iscal authority,
impose greater audience costs for default, and facilitate greater economic
transparency (e.g., Archer et al., 2007;Beaulieu et al., 2012;Biglaiser and
Staats, 2012;Cox and Saiegh, 2018;Hollyer et al., 2011;North and Weingast,
1989;Stasavage, 2003;Schultz and Weingast, 2003;Tomz and Wright,
2013).
2
Although democratic institutions may assuage investorsconcerns re-
garding governmentswillingness to pay, elections also affect sovereign risk
assessments. When election outcomes are easy to predict, differences between
candidates generate concerns about future government policies, especially if
they portend partisan switches (Tomz, 2007;McGillivray and Smith, 2008).
This is especially likely when partisan shifts are signif‌icant (Bernhard and
Leblang, 2006;Vaaler et al., 2006); when a country has recently undergone
regime change (Frye, 2010); or when elected off‌icials face few institutional
2. But also see Ballard-Rosa (2016);Ballard-Rosa et al. (2021).
Brooks et al. 1503

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT