Solving the Oligopoly Problem: Turner'S Try

DOI10.1177/0003603X9604100407
Date01 December 1996
AuthorJohn E. Lopatka
Published date01 December 1996
Subject MatterArticle
The Antitrust BulletinlWinter 1996
Solving the oligopoly problem:
Turner's try
BY JOHN E. LOPATKA*
1. Introduction
843
Asmall number
of
sellers occupy amarket. How should the
antitrust laws respond? The question in various permutations has
befuddled courts, litigants, and scholars for the entire history of
the Sherman Act.' One of the most significant contributors to its
analysis
was Donald Turner. Particularly in
his
famous 1962
article
in
the
Harvard
Law
Review
J
Turner
articulates
an
approach to the so-called oligopoly problem that remains infIuen-
*Alumni Professor of Law, University of South Carolina.
AUTHOR'S NOTE: 1am grateful to Roger Blair, Don Dewey, and Bill Page
for
their comments on earlier drafts and for our numerous, enlightening
exchanges on the subject
of
oligopolies. They should not be held account-
able, however,
for
any errors I make or the views expressed in this
article.
15 U.S.C. §§ 1-8 (1988).
2Donald F. Turner, The Definition
of
Agreement Under the Sher-
man Act: Conscious Parallelism and Refusals to Deal, 75 HARV. L.
REV.
655 (1962).
©1996 by Federal LegalPublications. Inc.
844
The antitrust bulletin
tial today.' Turner argues that a few sellers who dominate a mar-
ket may well charge supracompetitive prices without entering into
what could appropriately be called an unlawful agreement, and
section 1
of
the Sherman Act therefore cannot stop them. Indeed,
depending on the characteristics of the market, Turner believed
that supracompetitive pricing is inevitable.
Turner's arguments drew fire, the sharpest marksman being
Richard Posner. He argues that supracompetitive pricing is never
inevitable, regardless
of
the number of sellers and the character of
the market, and that section 1 therefore can be used to attack it.4
3Arecent electronic search discloses that the article has been cited
in sixty-five opinions, including the recent cases of Alvord-Polk, Inc. v,
F. Schumacher &Co., 37 F.3d 996, 1014 (3d Cir. 1994), cert. denied,
115 S. Ct. 1691 (1995); Petruzzi's IGA Supermarkets, Inc. v. Darling-
Delaware Co., 998 F.2d 1224, 1244 (3d Cir.), cert. denied, 114 S. Ct. 554
(1993); In re Coordinated Pretrial Proceedings in Petroleum Products
Antitrust Litigation, 906 F.2d 432, 443 (9th Cir. 1990), cert. denied, 500
U.S. 959 (1991); Roland Mach.
CO.
V. Dresser Industries, 749 F.2d 380,
393 (7th Cir. 1984) (Posner, J.); Barry Wright Corp. V.
ITT
Grinnell
Corp., 724 F.2d 227 (1st Cir. 1983) (Breyer, J.); City of Tuscaloosa v.
Harcros Chemicals, Inc., 877 F. Supp. 1504, 1533 (N.D. Ala. 1995). The
Supreme Court has cited the article six times, including in its most recent
antitrust case. See Brown v. Pro Football, Inc., 116 S. Ct. 2116, 2122
(1996); City of Columbia v. Omni Outdoor Advertising, Inc., 499 U.S.
365, 396
n.l0
(1991) (Stevens, J., dissenting); First Natl. Bank of Ari-
zona v. Cities Service Co., 391 U.S.
253,287
n.18 (1968); Albrecht v.
Herald Co., 390 U.S. 145, 162 n.5, 163 n.7 (1968) (Harlan, J., dissent-
ing); United States v. General Motors Corp., 384 U.S. 127, 145 (1966);
White Motor Co. v. United States, 372 U.S. 253, 268 n.6 (1963) (Bren-
nan, J., concurring).
The term "oligopoly" has become somewhat ambiguous. In its nar-
row sense, it means a market consisting of a small number
of
sellers, rel-
ative to some appropriate standard. It is sometimes used in a broader
sense to identify a small number of sellers who behave in a way different
from
that
in which a
large
number of sellers in a competitive market
would behave. In this sense, it assumes that oligopolists behave interde-
pendently, each taking into account its rivals' reactions in making any
decision with a market impact. For clarity, I use the term in its narrow
sense throughout this article.
4Richard A. Posner, Oligopoly and the Antitrust Laws: A Suggested
Approach, 21
STAN.
L.
REV.
1562 (1969).
Oligopoly problem 845
Extending George Stigler's work." Posner contends that supra-
competitive pricing by multiple firms is always the product of
collusion, explicit or tacit. Though collusion, especially the tacit
kind, is often difficult to detect, he suggests using economic indi-
cia to uncover it and then applying conventional section 1 sanc-
tions to deter it.
Turner's foundational position fit comfortably in a strain of
the evolving economic literature. Notably, Edward Chamberlin
had, like Turner, concluded that the sellers in a concentrated mar-
ket with specified, plausible characteristics will independently
price at the monopoly level." Moreover, Turner's exposition was
an attempt to characterize the state of the law and, it turns out,
helped guide the law's future. At the time of Turner's writings,
the Supreme Court had all but held that mere conscious price par-
allelism-the
charging of the same, supracompetitive prices by
competing sellers with knowledge of their
rivals'
prices-does
not violate the antitrust laws.? The proposition was no doubt rein-
forced by Turner's analysis and, so bolstered, became abedrock
principle, launching in subsequent cases innumerable searches
for something more than simple parallelism,
for
"plus factors"
that would transform the defendants' conduct into an actionable
conspiracy.
See George J. Stigler, A Theory
of
Oligopoly, 72 J.
POL.
Ecox. 44
(1964), reprinted in
GEORGE
J.
STIGLER,
THE
ORGANIZATION
OF
INDUSTRY
39
(1968).
6See
EDWARD
H.
CHAMBERLIN,
THE
THEORY
OF
MONOPOLISTIC
COMPE-
TITION
46-51
(7th ed. 1960).
7See
Theatre
Enterprises,
Inc.
v.
Paramount
Film
Distributing
Corp., 346 U.S. 537 (1954). In
that
case, several motion picture distribu-
tors
and
producers
each
refused
to
grant
first-run
rights
to a
suburban
exhibitor.
The
Court held
that
insufficient evidence
existed
to compel a
directed verdict in favor
of
the
exhibitor and therefore upheld a
jury
ver-
dict
for
the
defendants.
But
the
Court
observed,
"
'[C]onscious
paral-
lelism'
has not
yet
read conspiracy out
of
the
Sherman
Act
entirely" (id.
at
541),
and
the
dictum
was
reasonably
understood
to mean
that
con-
sciously parallel pricing decisions, without
more,
would
not violate the
antitrust laws.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT