Solutions to the Asset Allocation Problem by Informed Respondents: The Significance of the Size‐of‐Bet and the 1/N Heuristic

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6296.2009.01166.x
Published date01 September 2009
Date01 September 2009
C
Risk Management and Insurance Review, 2009, Vol.12, No. 2, 251-271
SOLUTIONS TO THE ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEM
BY INFORMED RESPONDENTS:THE SIGNIFICANCE
OF THE SIZE-OF-BET AND THE 1/
N
HEURISTIC
Gordon L. Clark
Emiko Caerlewy-Smith
John C. Marshall
ABSTRACT
Asset allocation is a classic topic in the theory of finance and a crucial issue
for investment policy. Noted for its significance in driving pension fund per-
formance, it is also an issue that individual investors consider when designing
their investment portfolios. In theory, Markowitz and those following in his
wake have an optimal solution. In practice, however, we show that when asked
to allocate their own money to a set of asset classes (from relatively low risk
to high risk) in an experimental situation, most of our informed respondents
would vary their investment strategies according to the size-of-bet (the money
value of assets to be invested). Wealso show that most participants in the study
adopted one of three solutions to the posed problem only one of which could be
thought consistent with Benartzi and Thaler’s 1/nheuristic. Since respondent
Gordon L. Clark is with the Centre for the Environment, Oxford University, South Parks Road,
Oxford OX1304, United Kingdom; phone: +44-1865-285197; fax: +44-1865-285073; e-mail: gor-
don.clark@ouce.ox.ac.uk. Emiko Caerlewy-Smith is with the Centre for the Environment, Oxford
University, South Parks Road, Oxford OX1 3QY, United Kingdom; phone: +44-(0)20-7213-8950;
fax: +44-(0)20-7212-4418; e-mail: emiko.caerlewy-smith@ouce.ox.ac.uk. John C. Marshall (de-
ceased) was with the Department of Clinical Neurology,John Radcliffe Hospital, Oxford Univer-
sity, Oxford OX3 9DU, United Kingdom. Support for this article was provided by the National
Association of Pension Funds (NAPF). The authors thank Christine Farnish, David Gould, and
Geoff Lindey for their interest in the project. Helpful comments on the projectand related papers
have been made by Keith Ambachtsheer,John Evans, Simon Ford, Michael Orszag, Roger Urwin,
members of the NAPF Benefits and Investments Councils, participants at the NAPF Investment
Conference, the FT-NAPF Trustee Conference, the annual pensions conference at the University
of New South Wales (Sydney), and the ICPM Rotman School conference at the University of
Toronto.Our thanks go to Amy Dickman who provided assistance in the initial coding and anal-
ysis of the data and to Janelle Knox, Esther Lim, Kendra Strauss, and two anonymous referees
who commented on previous versions of the article. The first-named author benefited from con-
versations on the topic with Ashby Monk and Richard Zeckhauser and the exchange of research
with Anup Basu, Michael Drew,and Gur Huberman. The results and interpretations reported are
the sole responsibility of the authors; none of the above should be held to account for any errors,
omissions, or opinions expressed herein. This article was subject to double-blind peer review.
251
252 RISK MANAGEMENT AND INSURANCE REVIEW
solutions do not seem to be explained by formal education, professional
qualifications, or training, it is suggested that solutions to the asset allocation
problem are a product of strategies that mix intuitive responses to the initial
tranche of money with theoretical cum practical shared conventions. Solutions
to the asset allocation puzzle suggest that the size-of-bet could be a significant
consideration for many informed investors. In conclusion, suggestions are made
about taking forward closer scrutiny of these experimental results.
INTRODUCTION
Asset allocation is a classic topic in the theory of finance (Markowitz, 1952). It is also a
crucial strategic issue when pension funds and individuals plan their long-term invest-
ments. It is widely believed that asset allocation is the single most important decision
an investor can make when planning his or her long-term retirement income. Moreover,
the available evidence in the United Kingdom suggests that “long-run asset allocations,
however modelled, account for the bulk of the time-series variation in returns” (Blake
et al., 1999, p. 459).1
If left to individuals, however, it appears that asset allocation is subject to a variety
of behavioral and cognitive effects. Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988) noted that new
TIAA-CREF participants tended to allocate 401(k) pension assets on a 50/50 (bonds
and equities) basis with little change thereafter despite the long-term accumulation of
financial assets and changing age and status.2While the simplest of lifestyle and life-cycle
models of asset allocation suggest that participants should revisit their asset allocations
on a regular basis as they approach retirement, many participants do not. Information
awareness, prototypical decision trees, and devices designed to enhance individual
decision making appear to have only modest dampening effects on these shortcomings.
However, Benartzi and Thaler (2001) suggested that well-designed default settings in
pension plans can be effective in mitigating these problems.
There is a vibrant market for information and advice on asset allocation strategies
(see Canto, 2006). Similarly, pension fund consultants have developed techniques and
methods of analysis to cue decision making on this issue; risk budgeting, asset-liability
models, and performance metrics provide formal protocols that integrate asset allo-
cation with long-term decision making (Bauer et al., 2006). Even so, the evidence on
financial decision-making competence and consistency is not altogether encouraging.
For example, we have suggested that many U.K. pension fund trustees lack the funda-
mental knowledge and skills to be expert decision makers (Clark et al., 2006). Judgment
in these situations is highly dependent upon the level of formal education, professional
qualifications, and role-specific training (Clark et al., 2007).
In this article, we report results from our project on U.K. pension trustee decision mak-
ing using the experimental methods that are now familiar when testing (as opposed to
1Blake et al. (1999) believe that this reflects the management and organization of the U.K. invest-
ment industry (an issue of internal and external governance) whereas others, notably Campbell
and Viceira (2006), have a more theoretical argument based on modern portfolio theory appli-
cable to both defined benefit and defined contribution plans.
2TIAA-CREF is a private pension fund operating on behalf of many U.S. universities and foun-
dation employers. It offers participants defined contribution pension savings products with
IRS tax-preferred status (i.e., 401(k) eligible). It is one of the world’s largest private pension
providers.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT