Social learning with differentiated products

Date01 March 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12268
AuthorArthur Campbell
Published date01 March 2019
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.50, No. 1, Spring 2019
pp. 226–248
Social learning with differentiated products
Arthur Campbell
Learning from friends is a key process by which consumers acquire information about avail-
able products. This article embeds social learning in a model of firms producing differentiated
products. I consider how the structureof social relationships between consumers influences pric-
ing and welfare. In particular, how a variety of characteristics of social networks - distribution
of friendships, homophily, clustering, and correlations between an individual’s preferences and
number of friends - influence these outcomes. I also find conditions under which consumer aware-
ness and the sensitivity of demand to prices are useful measures of the informational efficiency
of markets.
1. Introduction
An important aspect of competition in differentiated product markets is how informed
consumers are about their available choices. In addition, consumers’ lack of information is
commonly identified as an important source of inefficiency in markets, and information provision
policies are often used to ameliorate it.1Learning from friends is one of the most significant
sources of information for consumers in making purchase decisions.2The objective of this article
is to study the role that social learning through a social network playsin determining both the nature
of competition between firms and the welfare of participants in a differentiated product market.3
I develop a model of differentiated Bertrand competition, on a line, where awarenessof each
firm’sproduct diffuses through friendships. An individual becomes aware of a product if a friend
Monash University; arthur.campbell@monash.edu.
I would like to thank Andrea Galeotti, Florian Ederer, Kristof Madarasz, Mushfiq Mobarak, and seminar participants at
EUI and LSE for their helpful comments.
1Examples of policies include agricultural outreach programs, energy auditing, and financial planning services. See
also academic studies such as Miller and Mobarak (2014) and BenYishay and Mobarak (2018) that attempt to leverage
information provision through social networks.
2Word of mouth has been shown to affect purchasing behavior in restaurant choices (Luca, 2016), book sales
(Chevalier and Mayzlin, 2006), banking (Keaveney, 1995), entertainment (Chintagunta, Gopinath, and Venkataraman,
2010), and technological products (Herr, Kardes, and Kim, 1991), as well as appliances and clothing (Richins, 1983).
The Word of Mouth Marketing Association has been acquired bythe Association of National Advertisers and this is no
longer freely available online. Also, Bughin et al. (2010) observe “Word of mouth is the primary factor behind 20 to 50
percent of all purchase decisions.”
3Grossman and Shapiro (1984), in their influential model of advertising and competition in a differentiated product
market, observe that “[t]he absence from our model of search, word-of-mouth and experience as sources of information
is an important omission.” One contribution of this article is to incorporate and analyze word of mouth in a differentiated
product market.
226 C2019, The RAND Corporation.
CAMPBELL / 227
has previously purchased it. My baseline model with two firms is very tractable, allowing one to
analytically derive solutions to the question of how a wide range of network characteristics affect
pricing and welfare.
In the baseline model with two firms, consumers are uniformly located on a line, and the
firms are located at opposite ends of the line. A unit mass of consumers must choose a product
to purchase. I assume that individuals learn about the available products from a second mass
of individuals who have previously purchased one or other of the products. A product is in a
consumer’s choice set if they have a friend who purchased that product. The intensity of price
competition is determined by the prevalence of consumers who are aware of both products and
may therefore respond to a change in price by either firm. In a symmetric equilibrium, these
will be individuals who are located equidistant from either firm and find out about the existence
of both firms from their friends. The social network influences price competition through its
effect on the probability that a marginal consumer will find out about both products. In my
model, inefficiencies arise due to individuals not buying from the firm located closest to them.
The welfare loss that results from buying from the wrong firm is largest for individuals located
close to one of the firms. Hence, the social network influences welfare through the likelihood
that individuals receive information about the firm located closest to them. My analysis finds the
characteristics of social networks that influence prices and welfare through these channels.
I find that increasing the number of friendships reduces prices and improveswelfare, whereas
a mean preserving spread in the distribution of friendships will increase prices and reduce welfare.
When individuals are more likely to have friends with similar product preferences, prices are
unaffected, but welfare is improved. I consider how correlation between a consumer’s product
preferences and their number of friends may influence prices and welfare. I show that when
individuals located further from marginal consumers (i.e., those closer to one of the firms) are
more likely to have more friends, welfarewill be higher. Furthermore, when marginal consumers
(individuals located furthest from any firm) have fewer friends, prices increase.
I also consider two common measures of how wellinfor med consumers are: average aware-
ness of products and sensitivity of demand to price. I study how these are related to welfare.
Intuitively, these measures will be positively correlated with the efficiency of consumer decision-
making. I find conditions under which the naive use of these metrics will correctly identify
markets with higher welfare and conditions under which they either cannot be distinguished (i.e.,
the metric is uncorrelated with welfare) or are misleading as to the efficiency of a market (i.e., the
metric is negatively correlated with welfare). In particular, when the distribution of friendships
through First Order Stochastic Dominant (FOSD) or Second Order Stochastic Dominant (SOSD)
(less dispersed) changes, these metrics move in an intuitive manner. However, when comparing
markets with different levels of homophily, the market with higher welfare will also exhibit lower
consumer awareness and the same sensitivity of demand. Also, when comparing two markets
with different correlations between an individual’s number of friends and product preference, a
market where demand is more sensitive to prices may have lower welfare than a market where
demand is less sensitive.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we discuss the related
literature. Section 3 develops the baseline model of social learning with differentiated products.
Section 4, we analyze the baseline model. In Section 5 weextend the model to consider homphily.
In Section 6 we consider a setting where there is correlation between an individual’s valuation
and connectedeness. We discuss further extensions to the model in Section 7. We conclude in
Section 8.
2. Related literature
I believe this article is the first to characterize how features of a social network between
consumers influence welfare and price competition in a differentiated product market. The article
is broadly related to a large body of literature in industrial organization that studies settings where
C
The RAND Corporation 2019.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT