Small Donors in Congressional Elections

Published date01 September 2019
AuthorMichael P. McDonald,Tyler Culberson,Suzanne M. Robbins
Date01 September 2019
DOI10.1177/1532673X18763918
Subject MatterArticles
https://doi.org/10.1177/1532673X18763918
American Politics Research
2019, Vol. 47(5) 970 –999
© The Author(s) 2018
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/1532673X18763918
journals.sagepub.com/home/apr
Article
Small Donors in
Congressional
Elections
Tyler Culberson1, Michael P. McDonald2,
and Suzanne M. Robbins2
Abstract
Candidates raise substantial sums of money to compete in federal elections.
Scholars and election observers are concerned by potential corruption
related to the reliance on donors who make significant contributions. One
reform effort to counterbalance large donors is encouraging small donor
participation. Still, some worry that ideologically extreme candidates are
best able to raise small donations. We analyze internal U.S. Federal Elections
Commission data to examine small donor giving in the 2006 through 2010
U.S. House elections. We find small donors may expand the scope of
participation, in that the supply of small donors is unrelated to income and
that all types of candidates—incumbents, their challengers, and open seat
candidates—are equally adept at attracting small donors. Candidates in the
most competitive races raise the most in small contributions. We temper
reformers’ enthusiasm, finding that ideologically extreme incumbents tend
to raise more money from small donors.
Keywords
campaign finance, small donors, elections
1The Campaign Finance Institute, Washington, DC, USA
2University of Florida, Gainesville, FL, USA
Corresponding Author:
Suzanne M. Robbins, University of Florida, 205 Anderson Hall, P.O. Box 117325, Gainesville,
FL 32611-7011, USA.
Email: suzanne.robbins@ufl.edu
763918APRXXX10.1177/1532673X18763918American Politics ResearchCulberson et al.
research-article2018
Culberson et al. 971
Introduction
Donating to political campaigns is a form of political participation. Unlike
voting, where each eligible citizen has only one vote in a geographically con-
strained race, citizens can donate to more than one candidate, across multiple
jurisdictions, up to regulated limits. Much has been made of the political
inequality resulting from a donor class of “fat cats” who underwrite American
elections. Early research noted that “the bulk of political money is supplied
by a relatively small number of people” (Heard, 1962, p. 48). If, as studies
find, wealthy individuals are more likely to donate, and if elected officials are
responsive to these “monetary surrogate” constituents (Mansbridge, 2003, p.
523), then policy outcomes may favor the wealthy (e.g., Bartels, 2005), and
distort representation in favor of a minority with more resources (e.g., Farrar-
Myers & Dwyre, 2008). To counter the potential corrupting effect of large
donors, some in the reform community have revived arguments to empower
small and local donors thus “ . . . expanding the range of citizens who can
participate in the political process” (Bauer & Potter, 2013; see also Corrado,
Malbin, Mann, & Ornstein, 2010; Potter & Morgan, 2013).
Public concern over large donations and the merits of empowering small
donors date to the Progressive Era (Mutch, 2014; Weyl, 1913). Parties and
candidates have pursued the “small donor” over time, even if for little more
than good public relations. As then-Senator John Warner (R-VA) noted, “Of
all the sources of private monies, the most desirable and least controversial is
that contributed by instate individuals in small amounts” (cited in Rosenberg,
2002, p. 1). Despite the desirability of small donors, some argue candidates’
pursuit of small contributors is an inefficient use of campaign time and
resources (Gais, 1998; Heard, 1962; Sorauf, 1988). Candidates for federal
office must raise large sums of money to fund their expensive campaigns, so
it is more economical to raise money from a large donor than many small
donors. Advances in technology have perhaps changed this calculus by
reducing candidate costs to cultivate small donors (Christenson, Smidt, &
Panagopoulos, 2014; Malbin, 2013). Furthermore, a handful of places such
as New York City and Los Angeles have enacted reforms such as matching
small donations to encourage more small donor activity (Malbin, 2013;
Malbin, Brusoe, & Glavin, 2012); others advocate for publicly funded vouch-
ers that citizens may donate to candidates (i.e., Hasen, 2016).
What might be expected if reforms are adopted to encourage small dona-
tions and if candidates more often pursue them? Wilcox (2008) finds both
ideologically extreme and moderate candidates successfully use the Internet
to attract small donors. Moreover, ideologically extreme individuals are well
known to participate at high rates in voluntary campaign activities, including

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT