SM Bonds—A New Product for Managing Longevity Risk

Published date01 March 2019
AuthorShauna Ferris,Piet Jong
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jori.12203
Date01 March 2019
©2017 The Journal of Risk and Insurance. Vol.86, No. 1, 121–149 (2019).
DOI: 10.1111/jori.12203
SM Bonds—A New Product for Managing
Longevity Risk
Piet de Jong
Shauna Ferris
Abstract
A new type of retirement bond is proposed called an SM bond. SM bonds
are long dated government bonds divisible into two parts: a survivorship
(S) part and a mortality (M) part. Each SM bond is associated with a par-
ticular age. SM bonds associated with a particular age are only purchasable
by (originators) of that age. The SM bond is then splittable into an S and M
component. The S part must be retained by the originator, who receives the
face value of the bond if he/she is alive at maturity.For originators who die
prior to the maturity date, the maturity value of the SM bond is assigned to a
mortality pool. The holder of the M part of the bond receives the annual bond
coupon, and at maturity a pro rata share of the mortality pool. M bonds are
tradable: holders can sell their M bonds to anyone, at any time. It is envisaged
different age bonds are issued every year for ages say 30–64 each with say
a 35-year term. The market will be regularly informed about the mortality
experience, and the market price of the M bonds will vary over time to reflect
that experience.
Introduction
SM bonds proposed in this article aim to address key problem areas for individuals
planning their retirement, for governments grappling with budgetary problems due
to the social security demands of an aging population, and for the private sector
attempting to develop, market, and price longevity products. SM bonds will facilitate:
1. The ability of individuals to, in effect, buy government-guaranteed retirement in-
come streams at competitive market prices.
2. The ability of governments to directly facilitate and incentivize retirement income
planning by individuals, whereby incentivized savings can be used to provide for
individual retirement income streams that cannot be capitalized before death and
cannot be passed to heirs.
3. The ability of governments to absolve themselves of longevity risk.
4. The operation of transparent and deep longevity risk markets.
Piet de Jong and Shauna Ferris are at the Department of Applied Finance and Actuar-
ial Studies Macquarie University, Sydney, NSW 2109. De Jong can be contacted via e-mail:
piet.dejong@mq.edu.au.
121
122 The Journal of Risk and Insurance
Individuals planning for retirement face a great deal of uncertainty: uncertainty about
their own lifespan, uncertainty about future investment returns on retirementsavings,
and uncertainty about the future cost of living. Retirees can manage these risks by
purchasing indexed lifetime annuities. Economic models, such as those presented in
Yaari(1965) and extended by many others (Davidoff et al., 2005), suggest that rational,
risk-averse, utility-maximizing investors should invest at least part of their savings
in lifetime annuities.
Despite this theory,retirees appear reluctant to buy lifetime annuities. This reluctance
has been observed in annuity markets in several different countries (Rusconi, 2006;
Brown, 2009). The discrepancy between the theoretically optimal behavior and ob-
served behavior is commonly described as the “annuity puzzle” (Modigliani, 1988;
Benartzi et al., 2011).
Many authors (Antolin, 2008; Brown et al., 2008; Brown, 2009; Rusconi, 2008; Lloyd,
2014) have attempted to explain the annuity puzzle. Possible explanations include:
rCost. Surveys have shown that many retirees regard lifetime annuities, purchased
from life insurance companies, as poor value for money. Lifetime annuities can be
expensive (for reasons given in later on in this article).
rLiquidity needs. Lifetime annuities provide a predetermined sum of money each
year, and do not usually allow for ad hoc withdrawals. Retirees may well be con-
cerned about the availability of money to cover unexpected large expenses, for
example, health care costs or the cost of home repairs. Flexibility and control are
important for many retirees (Stewart, 2007; Beshears et al., 2014; Echalier et al.,
2015).
rBequest motives. Lifetime annuities usually cease on the death of the annuitant.
The retiree may wish to provide bequests to others.
rHealth status. Those in poor health (or with shorter life expectancies than the aver-
age annuitant) may be especially reluctant to buy lifetime annuities, since the value
of benefits received is likely to be lower than the cost of the annuity. Economic mod-
els allowing for health uncertainties indicate that this might explain the low level
of demand for annuities (Reichling and Smetters, 2013).
rSocial security interactions. The retiree may prefer to spend money maintaining a
better standard of living in the early years of retirement, and then rely on govern-
ment provided safety-net benefits to cover income needs at advanced ages. Safety-
net systems might “crowd out” annuity products. The potential for “crowding out”
will depend on the design of the safety-net system; hence, demand for annuities
may vary across countries (Rusconi, 2008).
rInsolvency risk. The retiree may be concerned about the risk that the annuity
provider (a pension fund or insurance company) will become insolvent and hence
fail to pay promised benefits. Beshears et al. (2014) find that “worry that the com-
pany may not be able to pay me in the future” was a key concern for American
survey respondents.
rFinancial illiteracy and poor decision making. People may have trouble under-
standing annuity products (which are often quite complex) and/or may have a
poor understanding of the risks arising from reliance on account-based retirement

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT