Slow to Learn

AuthorWilliam Spaniel,Peter Bils
Published date01 April 2018
Date01 April 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/0022002716662688
Subject MatterArticles
Article
Slow to Learn: Bargaining,
Uncertainty, and the
Calculus of Conquest
William Spaniel
1,2
and Peter Bils
3
Abstract
If peace fails due to incomplete information and incentives to misrepresent power or
resolve, war is supposed to serve as a learning process and allows parties to reach a
mutually preferable bargain. We explore crisis bargaining under a third type of
uncertainty: the extent to which one side wishes to conquer the other. With
incomplete information and take-it-or-leave-it negotiations, this type of uncertainty
is isomorphic to incomplete information about the probability of victory. However,
with incomplete information and bargaining while fighting, standard convergence
results fail: types fail to fully separate because there is no differential cost for delay.
Wars correspondingly last longer while benefiting no one. These results help explain
empirical differences between territorial versus nonterritorial conflicts and inter-
state versus intrastate wars.
Keywords
bargaining, game theory, civil wars, interstate conflict
Consider the Taliban’s dilemma in September 2001. While the United States made
evident its desire to capture Osama bin Laden, whether Washington and its allies
wanted to pursue regime change in Afghanistan was unclear. Indeed, in the weeks
1
Department of Political Science, University of Pittsburgh, Pittsburgh, PA, USA
2
Center for International Security and Cooperation, Stanford University, Stanford, CA, USA
3
Department of Political Science, University of Rochester, Rochester, NY, USA
Corresponding Author:
William Spaniel, Department of Political Science, Posvar Hall, University of Pittsburgh, Pittsburgh,
PA 15260.
Email: williamspaniel@gmail.com
Journal of Conflict Resolution
2018, Vol. 62(4) 774-796
ªThe Author(s) 2016
Reprints and permission:
sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0022002716662688
journals.sagepub.com/home/jcr
between September 11 and the invasion of Afghanista n, declassified documents
reveal that the United States attempted to reach a settlement that would keep the
Taliban in power (see http://nsarchive.gwu.edu/NSAEBB/NSAEBB358a/
doc09.pdf). Yet these negotiations failed. Communication alone could not resolve
the Taliban’s uncertainty; if wanting to impose maximalist postwar divisions
increases an opponent’s willingness to mak e concessions, then more minimalist
types might want to bluff accordingly.
1
Similar issues have been at the root of conflicts involving Russia, Georgia, and
the South Ossetian and Abkhazian autonomous regions. The Georgian government
has sought to reign in autonomy with a pair of civil wars, one at the end of the Cold
War and another in 2008. Throughout the process, however, it has remained unclear
whether Georgia would ultimately find complete control over these regions to be
worth the cost, or if its ideal feasible outcome is to merely increase integration. This
is problematic for Russians, South Ossetians, and Abkhazians, who might wish to
maximize autonomy. Indeed, standing firm could risk future military conflict with
Georgia, while conceding some autonomy would increase the likelihood of peace at
the price of some self-determination.
Scholars of international relations appreciate these strategic choices states make
after victory (Ikenberry 2009). However, the literature remains quiet on how post-
victory expectations affect bargaining behaviors before and during a war. This
article takes a step in that direction. While the logic of crisis bargaining is straight-
forward when states know of their opponents’ postwar intentions, asymmetric uncer-
tainty over these plans leads to complex and unexpected strategic behaviors.
2
Initially, a reader familiar with the literature on bargaining and war may
assume that uncertainty over conquest may quickly reduce to a simpl e risk-
return trade-off, that is, states weigh the relative likelihood of facing a
conquest-willing type versus a conquest-hesitant type against the costs of war
and select a strategy that maximizes the trade-off. The results we present below
indicate otherwise. Uncertainty over the extent one side wishes to conquer the
other leads to identical results as uncertainty over the probability of victory in
one-shot negotiations. If, however, we allow bargaining to continue while the
states fight, then equilibrium expectations diverge: whereas learning can occur
relatively rapidly with uncertainty over power, the incentive to bluff is stronger in
the case we develop. Thus, wars last longer when uncertainty over conquest is at
the root of conflict.
Some intuition will clarify our findings. With uncertainty over power, opposing
types have differential rewards for fighting each battle. This is because more pow-
erful types are more likely to prevail in each confrontation, putting themselves in a
better bargaining position that a less powerful type cannot mimic. In turn, if the
opponent wishes to, it can offer an amount up front that a weaker type would be
willing to accept but that a stronger type would not accept. Therefore, the negoti-
ating process leading up to battle reveals substantial information, allowing the
opponent to settle with the stronger type afterward.
3
Spaniel and Bils 775

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT