SKEWNESS AND COSKEWNESS IN BOND RETURNS

Published date01 June 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jfir.12093
Date01 June 2016
AuthorI‐Hsuan Ethan Chiang
SKEWNESS AND COSKEWNESS IN BOND RETURNS
I-Hsuan Ethan Chiang
University of North Carolina at Charlotte
Abstract
Bond skewness and coskewness (i.e., bond return comovement with market volatility)
are both time varying, with cross-sectional variation driven by maturity and credit rating.
Other things being equal, longer maturity bonds have lower skewness, and lower
coskewness with respect to the bond market index; lower quality bonds have lower
skewness, and higher coskewness with respect to the bond market index. Three-moment
bond alphas (which account for coskewness effects) are time varying and predictable by
market default spread. They are signicantly different from, and often are closer to zero
than, two-moment alphas (which ignore coskewness effects).
JEL Classification: G12
I. Introduction
In this article, I explore properties of the third momentsskewness and coskewness (an
assets return comovement with market volatility)in discrete holding-period bond
returns. I ask three empirical questions: Do bonds have signicant skewness or
coskewness? What drives cross-sectional and time-series variations in bond skewness
and coskewness? How are bond alphas, after beta and coskewness risks are controlled,
related to bond attributes and macroeconomic variables?
Using panel regressions to separately analyze term premium (via a Treasury
bond data set) and default premium (via a corporate bond data set), I nd that U.S. bond
returns display time-varying skewness and coskewness, whose cross-sectional variation
is driven by maturity and credit rating. Other bond attributes (including convexity and
current yield) and macroeconomic variables (e.g., short rate, term spread, default spread,
and interest rate volatility) also explain the time series and the cross-section of third
I am greatly indebted to my advisors: Wayne Ferson, Pierluigi Balduzzi, David Chapman, Edith Hotchkiss,
and Alan Marcus for their encouragement and helpful discussions. I am grateful to Harry Turtle (the associate
editor) and Scott Cederburg (the referee) for their numerous constructive suggestions and comments. This paper
has beneted from useful comments of Sirio Aramonte (discussant), Evangelos Aspiotis (discussant), Te-Feng
Chen (discussant), Ying Duan, Philip Dybvig, Roger Edelen, Richard Evans, Clifford Holderness, Kris Jacobs
(discussant), Edward Kane, Min Kim, Darren Kisgen, Chung-Ming Kuan, Justin Kuan, Xinxin Li, Wilson Liu
(discussant), David McLean, Fabio Moneta, Jeffrey Pontiff, Karl Snow (discussant), Philip Strahan, Hassan
Tehranian, Dengli Wang (discussant), and seminar participants at Academia Sinica, Boston College, University
of Connecticut, DePaul University, HKU, HKUST, University of Iowa, Southern Methodist University,
SUNYAlbany, SUNYBuffalo, University of North Carolina at Charlotte, University of Waterloo, the Seventh
Trans-Atlantic Doctoral Conference at London Business School, and the annual meetings of the 2007 Southern
Finance Association, 2008 Washington Area Finance Association, 2008 Northern Finance Association, 2008
Financial Management Association, and 2012 Midwest Finance Association. I also thank Kenneth French for
providing access to his online data library. All remaining errors are solely mine.
The Journal of Financial Research Vol. XXXIX, No. 2 Pages 145178 Summer 2016
145
© 2016 The Southern Finance Association and the Southwestern Finance Association
RAWLS COLLEGE OF BUSINESS, TEXAS TECH UNIVERSITY
PUBLISHED FOR THE SOUTHERN AND SOUTHWESTERN
FINANCE ASSOCIATIONS BY WILEY-BLACKWELL PUBLISHING
moments of bonds. When implementing a conditional three-moment two-index model on
the data sets, I nd that three-moment bond alphas (which adjust for coskewness risk) are
time varying and predictable using the market default spread. They are signicantly
different from, and often are closer to zero than, two-moment alphas (which ignore
coskewness effects).
This article makes the following contributions. First, from the portfolio
management and performance evaluation perspectives, I focus on the estimation of
skewness and coskewness in bond returns, whereas extant empirical research mainly
explores higher moments of stock returns. Second, both skewness and coskewness are
determined by three categories of predictive variables jointly: static bond attributes,
time-varying bond attributes, and time-varying macroeconomic variables. Very few
existing studies explore variations in the third moments, and those that do focus on time-
series aspects. Third, I provide a simple and unifying approach for portfolio managers
whose asset selectivity and market-timing ability are subject to evaluation. As the three
categories of predictive variables are observable in real time and the estimation
procedure is regression based, portfolio managers will nd the alpha (representing asset
selectivity) and coskewness (resembling market-timing ability) estimators useful.
Fourth, I identify two bond attributesmaturity and credit ratingthat drive the cross-
sectional variation in bond skewness and coskewness. These attributes enter various risk
measures in different ways.
Classical mean-variance portfolio analysis connes its focus to the rst two
moments of returns, assuming that the distributions of asset returns are fully
characterized by the rst two moments (as in a normal distribution) or assuming that
investors do not care about higher moments. The resulting equilibrium asset pricing
model is Sharpes (1964) and Lintners (1965) two-momentcapital asset pricing
model (CAPM). However, returns are asymmetric empirically, and intuitively an
investor prefers a positively skewed payoff because it implies substantial chances of
large payoffs. Arditti (1967), Arrow (1971), Kraus and Litzenberger (1976), and Scott
and Horvath (1980) show that risk-averse investors with nonincreasing absolute risk
aversion (ARA) have a positive preference for portfolio skewness, and Kraus and
Litzenberger (1976) and Simkowitz and Beedles (1978) discuss portfolios featuring such
a preference.
1
Arditti (1967) relates stock returns to total skewness, and Barberis and
Huang (2008) provide theoretical justication using prospect theory. In the same vein,
Kraus and Litzenberger (1976, 1983) take a rational perspective and advocate a three-
moment CAPM, in which both covariance and coskewness drive cross-sectional
variation in expected asset returns. Kraus and Litzenberger (1976), Friend and
Westereld (1980), Barone Adesi (1985), Sears and Wei (1988), Lim (1989), and Barone
Adesi, Gagliardini, and Urga (2004) nd mixed empirical evidence for the three-moment
model using equity market data. Recent literature introduces conditioning information
1
A risk-averse investors preference for positive skewness can be formally motivated by a cubic
approximation of an expected utility function with nonincreasing ARA (see Arditti 1967; Arrow 1971). Although
Levy (1969) points out that the domain for wealth is restricted when a cubic approximation is imposed, Arditti
(1969) shows that nonincreasing ARA applies to general forms of utility functions and thus is not subject to Levys
critique.
146 The Journal of Financial Research
in this context. Harvey and Siddique (1999, 2000), Smith (2007), and Chang,
Christoffersen, and Jacobs (2013) all nd that conditional coskewness matters in equity
returns. Patton (2004) nds conditional skewness matters in forming optimal stock
portfolios.
2
A growing literature (e.g., Fang and Lai 1997; Dittmar 2002; Ang, Chen, and
Xing 2006; Chung, Johnson, and Schill 2006) extends to even higher moments than
skewness, or to other comoments (Boguth 2010). However, the empirical literature on
skewness and coskewness has largely ignored bond returns.
In this article, I study the cross-sectional and time-series properties of skewness
and coskewness in discrete holding-period bond returns.
3
The cash-ow structure of
bonds motivates asymmetry in bond returns. Unlike stock prices, bond prices face an
upper bound: the maximum price of a bond is the sum of future promised cash ows, and
thus bond returns are skewed by nature. Furthermore, convexity, regime switching in
state variables, default risk, or underlying callability or putability may also create
asymmetry in bond returns. Therefore, it is important to examine whether discrete bond
returns have nontrivial higher moments and how they affect investment decisions.
The crucial empirical issue is what portfolio management content the third
moments in bond returns carry. Suppose an investor has a preference for positive
skewness. When he holds only one asset, obviously he cares about the assets asymmetry
measure on a stand-alone basisthe total skewness of that asset. But, when he holds
portfolios, he cares about an assets asymmetry measure on a portfolio basisthe
coskewnessof that asset. Statistically, coskewness measures an assets marginal
contribution to portfolio skewness; thus, positive coskewness in an asset is desirable
because it makes the portfolio more positively skewed.
4
As coskewness is typically
formulated as the comovement of an assets return with portfolio volatility, an economic
interpretation of an assets coskewness is its ability to hedge against shocks to portfolio
volatility. Consider that when the stock market becomes more volatile and distressed,
investors tend to sell their equity holdings and buy Treasury bonds. This typical ight to
qualitybehavior is reected in Treasury bondspositive coskewness with respect to the
stock market index. However, riskier bonds do not have Treasury bondsdistinct
insurance feature and behave like most stocks when the stock market is distressed,
exhibiting negative coskewness with respect to the stock market index. My empirical
evidence shows that Treasury bonds have positive coskewness with respect to the stock
market index, whereas corporate bonds have negative coskewness with respect to the
stock market index. With the possible sign differences, the third-moment asset pricing
and portfolio choice implications in xed-income securities have the potential to be
richer than those in stocks, as empirically most stocks have negative skewness and
negative coskewness with respect to the stock market index.
2
Skewness in other nancial instruments has been studied in the literature, including foreign exchange (Peir
o
1999), futures (Eastman and Lucey 2008), and lottery tickets (Bhattacharyya and Garrett 2008).
3
The amount of attention this article pays to third moments has a theoretical justication: Kraus and
Litzenberger (1983) show that individual preferences for positive skewness can be aggregated so that the
representative investor has a similar preference; however, preference for kurtosis cannot be aggregated.
4
The coskewness formulation in this article is motivated by Barone Adesi, Gagliardini, and Urga (2004); see
Section II for a discussion on alternative coskewness measures.
Skewness and Coskewness 147

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT