Are short‐term effects of pollution important for growth and optimal fiscal policy?

Published date01 September 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12438
Date01 September 2020
J Public Econ Theory. 2020;22:12621288.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet1262
|
© 2020 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Received: 16 August 2018
|
Accepted: 14 February 2020
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12438
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Are shortterm effects of pollution important
for growth and optimal fiscal policy?
Sugata Ghosh
1
|Trishita Ray Barman
2
|Manash Ranjan Gupta
3
1
Department of Economics and Finance,
Brunel University, Uxbridge,
Middlesex, UK
2
Department of Economics, Shiv Nadar
University, Gautam Buddha Nagar,
Uttar Pradesh, India
3
Economics Research Unit, Indian
Statistical Institute, Kolkata, West Bengal,
India
Correspondence
Trishita Ray Barman, Department of
Economics, Shiv Nadar University, NH91
Tehsil Dadri, Gautam Buddha Nagar
201314, UP, India.
Email: trbarman@gmail.com
Abstract
We study optimal fiscal policy in a stockflow model
of the environment within an endogenous growth
framework, where some pollutants have a lasting
impact on environmental quality which is restored
through abatement expenditure, while others dis-
sipate and hence, have a shortterm effect on the
environment. All pollutants, however, affect the
productivity of a public good negatively. Given that
shortterm pollution, although it dissipates, is irre-
versible in this sense, a government cannot ignore its
negative effects since this type of pollution lowers the
productivity of all inputs. We find that a larger ne-
gative effect of shortterm pollutants as well as a
higher congestion effect of private capital leads to
corrective fiscal policies with higher optimal income
tax and abatement expenditure rates, which have
favorable growth consequences. Interestingly, we
find that the rate of shortterm pollution does not
affect optimal fiscal policy while that of the longterm
pollution does.
1|INTRODUCTION
Future generations would be worse off if unsustainable consumption and investment patterns
of today translate after a time lag into environmental disruption, as Smulders (1995) points out.
The challenge, therefore, is to achieve sustained economic growth with maximum achievable
social welfare levels preserving the quality of the environment as much as possible. Since fiscal
policy can be used to attain such objectives, it is appropriate to understand the nature of
taxation and expenditure policies that could effectively counter environmental pollution while
preserving growth prospects. In this paper, we study two different kinds of impact of en-
vironmental pollution on optimal fiscal policies. Some types of pollution generate flow effects
while some other types generate longterm effects on environmental quality which accumulate
over time, like a stock variable. To the best of our knowledge, the dissipating and the lasting
effects of pollution have not been studied simultaneously in the dynamic endogenous growth
models available in the existing environmentgrowth literature.
An important issue in this context is the distinction not only between stocks and flows but
also between longterm (permanent) effects and shortterm (dissipating) effects.
1
Some pollu-
tants, or part of them, dissipate or are absorbed by the environment. So, they do not stay on in
the environment long enough to have lasting impacts on it. On the other hand, those pollutants
which stay on and have negative effects on the environment affect the stock of environmental
quality. It is well known why abatement activities are necessary to curb longterm pollution.
However, what is less obvious, and therefore, required, is to examine the need to control short
term pollutants. Even if they dissipate, it may be necessary to control shortterm pollutants
because these pollutants can also produce substantial negative effects on productivity.
Environmental pollution affects the productivity of inputs in various ways. In particular, we
follow Ray Barman and Gupta (RBG, 2010) to model the way the services from public infra-
structure are adversely affected by pollution, and the manner in which the productivity of
private capital is affected in the process. One could think of a public good, like a highway being
corroded by acid rain, which is caused by the prolonged presence of atmospheric pollutants, like
sulphur dioxide, nitrous oxide, and so forth; or, in other words, by the degradation of the stock
of environmental quality as a whole which causes the acid rains. This could result in potholes
slowing movement of traffic and can cause hazards, like accidents too. Pollutants causing acid
rain are instrumental in corroding not only roads, but also buildings and other physical in-
frastructure. This damage may be prevented by maintaining the stock of environmental quality
if adequate expenditure is made on abatement.
This highway example can also be used to capture the shortterm effects of pollution in the
production function. For example, vehicle drivers on the highways are slowed down because of
drop in visibility caused by the presence of smog. However, the smog usually disappears after a
point in time, and the driver can revert to their original speed. This is an example
2
of the short
term effect of certain pollutants that affects efficiency for some time.
We attempt to capture the simultaneous impact of stock and flow effects of pollutants on
growth in a unified framework. Lieb (2004) also considers the simultaneous occurrence of stock
1
The stockflow distinction mentioned here in the context of environment as a public good is different from that made
in the context of public goods, in general. In the context of public goods it involves the longterm goal of the accu-
mulation of public capitalfor example, building of infrastructure networks (stocks)and the shortterm need to
provide public servicesfor example, maintenance of such networks (flows). And governments routinely have to face
tradeoffs between these two objectives. A model of public goods having both a stock as well as a flow component is
captured by Ghosh and Roy (2004). However, even the shortterm maintenance expenditure made in case of other
public good stocks is to keep the stock of public good in running condition so that the flow of services from it continues
to flow unabated. So, whether it is augmenting of the stock or maintaining it, the stock of public good is affected. This is
not so with shortterm pollution, which is part of total flow of emissions, as we model in our paper here. It does not
affect the stock of environmental quality and yet has productivity effects, independently.
2
Other examples of flow effects of pollutants can be provided. Biodegradable waste and sewage in water makes it unfit
for use in agriculture or factories. Depletion of nitrogenous compounds due to intensive cropping, though eventually
replenished by nature, affects current harvest. Brick kilns cannot use clay polluted by sewage waste. These are examples
of shortterm pollution affecting productivity. On the other hand, longterm pollution, like soil quality degradation due
to the presence of lead, the chemical effluents from one industry impacting another industry using the same water
source, and so forth, clearly has longterm negative impact on industrial production.
GHOSH ET AL.
|
1263

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT