Shifting the Fat‐Tailed Distribution of Blockbuster Punitive Damages Awards

AuthorW. Kip Viscusi,Benjamin J. McMichael
Published date01 June 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jels.12043
Date01 June 2014
Shifting the Fat-Tailed Distribution of
Blockbuster Punitive Damages Awards
W. Kip Viscusi and Benjamin J. McMichael*
The distribution of blockbuster punitive damages awards has fat tails similar to the distri-
butions of losses from natural disasters. Extremely large awards occur more often and are
more difficult to predict than if blockbuster awards were distributed normally. The size and
predictability of awards are important factors in the U.S. Supreme Court’s decisions on
punitive damages. This article examines the effect of the Court’s decision in State Farm v.
Campbell on blockbuster punitive damages awards. State Farm shifts the fat tail of the distri-
bution of blockbuster awards down (or “thins” the tail), which is consistent with a restraining
effect on award size. State Farm reduces the size of blockbuster awards in general, but this
reduction is most salient in the upper half of the distribution of awards. State Farm also has
a negative influence on the probability of exceeding a single-digit ratio between punitive and
compensatory damages. This article also examines the largest awards and considers why
defendants may not pay large punitive damages awards.
I. Introduction
Punitive damages share with natural disasters the property that there are often extremely
large outliers that are not consistent with a normal distribution. More specifically,
extremely large punitive damages awards are characterized by a fat-tailed distribution. For
natural disasters, these outliers take the form of extremely large losses. In the case of
punitive damages, it is the magnitude of the awards that may be especially great.
In this article, we focus specifically on what Viscusi (2004), Hersch and Viscusi
(2004), and Del Rossi and Viscusi (2010) have termed blockbuster punitive damages
awards, that is, punitive damages awards of at least $100 million. Much like losses from
significant natural disasters, these awards are extreme outliers and potentially pose cata-
strophic financial risks to defendants. However, courts can limit the economic impact of
these awards in two principal ways. First, U.S. Supreme Court decisions and state punitive
damages limits can affect the magnitude of the awards. Second, courts can reduce or
overturn these awards on appeal or through other postverdict procedures. This article
*Address correspondence to W. Kip Viscusi, University Distinguished Professor of Law, Economics, and Management,
Vanderbilt University Law School, 131 21st Ave. S., Nashville, TN 37203; email: kip.viscusi@vanderbilt.edu.
McMichael is JD/PhD Student, Vanderbilt Law and Economics Program.
We acknowledge a variety of helpful comments from two referees.
bs_bs_banner
Journal of Empirical Legal Studies
Volume 11, Issue 2, 350–377, June 2014
350
examines the distribution and determinants of blockbuster awards and the ways in which
the courts have restrained their economic impact.
Punitive damages serve a unique function in the U.S. civil justice system. They are
essentially the only civil remedy that exists to punish defendants and deter future wrong-
doers as opposed to compensating plaintiffs for specific harms or preventing those harms
from recurring in the future. The U.S. Supreme Court has repeatedly held that states may
authorize punitive damages only for the limited purposes of punishment and deterrence.
Because these awards exist to punish and deter, the amount that any individual plaintiff may
receive does not adhere to a well-defined formula. Unlike compensatory damages, which
must be calibrated to a specific harm, adjudicators must decide what amount of damages
will adequately achieve the more nebulous social goals of punishment and deterrence.
When deciding what amount to award plaintiffs, adjudicators often receive very little
guidance regarding the amount of punitive damages that is appropriate, leading some
observers to question extremely large awards.1
The U.S. Supreme Court has never instructed lower courts on exactly how they
should award punitive damages, despite the potential for extremely large awards, but it has
provided some general guidance on what awards are unconstitutionally large. After author-
izing punitive damages under the Constitution in its earlier cases,2the Court began to limit
the size of awards and the process by which they are awarded in the 1990s and 2000s under
the Due Process Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment. Currently, three main cases state
the constitutional doctrine on punitive damages: BMW of North America, Inc. v. Gore (1996),
State Farm v. Campbell (2003), and Philip Morris USA v. Williams (2007). All three cases
consistently hold that the only legitimate purposes for which states may authorize punitive
damages are punishment and deterrence. In all three cases, the Court seeks to limit “grossly
excessive” awards that violate notions of fundamental fairness, do not provide adequate
notice to parties that they may be subject to large awards, and do not further the legitimate
interests of the state. In limiting these excessive awards, the Court in BMW provided three
general guideposts that lower courts must consider when determining whether a given
punitive award is “reasonable” under the Fourteenth Amendment: (1) the reprehensibility
of the defendant’s conduct, (2) the “disparity” between the harm inflicted on the plaintiff
and the punitive damages award, and (3) the difference between the award and civil
penalties authorized for similar cases.3
State Farm clarified the Court’s decision in BMW by explaining that the reprehensi-
bility of the defendant’s conduct is the most important factor in evaluating the reasonable-
ness of a particular punitive damages award. State Farm will also play a central role in our
1For a discussion of the types of guidance received by adjudicators, see Sunstein et al. (2002). In general, awarding
punitive damages may be efficient from the standpoint of deterrence, depending on the relationship between the
probability of detecting the defendant’s wrongful behavior and the amount of compensatory damages. Polinsky and
Shavell (1998) provide a thorough overview of the economic theory of punitive damages, but there is little evidence
that courts have adhered to the economic prescriptions for efficient levels of punitive damages.
2Pacific Mutual Life Ins. v. Haslip, 499 U.S. 1 (1991).
3These guideposts were initially announced in BMW of North America v. Gore, 517 U.S. 559 (1996).
Shifting the Fat-Tailed Distribution of Blockbuster Awards 351

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT