Sharing contracts' marginalisation, adverse selection and markup calculation

Published date01 March 2018
Date01 March 2018
AuthorFayçal Amrani
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12510
SPECIAL ISSUE ARTICLE
Sharing contractsmarginalisation, adverse
selection and markup calculation
Fayc
ßal Amrani
Department of Economics, Paris-Dauphine University, Paris, France
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Sharing contracts have founded the original paradigm of contemporary Islamic finance while
markup contracts were conceived only as subsidiary financing tools. Earlier contemporary Islamic
literature (Haque & Mirakhor, 1986; Khan, 1984; Naqvi, 1982; Siddiqi, 1991) has been dedicated
to present sharing contracts and defend the relevance of a financial system they can constitute.
Thereafter, several authors (e.g., Al-Suwailem, 2003; Presley & Sessions, 1994) have attempted
to demonstrate the superiority of sharing contracts on fixed income contracts (whether conven-
tional or Islamic).
However, the practices of Islamic financial institutions
1
have gradually moved away from this
original paradigm; sharing contracts have given way to markup ones. This assessment is made by sev-
eral authors, for mixed financial systemslike that of Egyptas well as full-fledged Islamic systems
like that of Iran (e.g., Aggarwal & Yousef, 2000; Dar & Presley, 2001; Yasseri, 2002).
2
Even in
Malaysiawhich is one of the most important markets of Islamic financesharing arrangements are
very marginal representing only 0.5% of assets (Chong & Liu, 2009). Several theoretical contr ibu-
tions have attempted to explain this sharing paradigms failure. Most of them base their argumenta-
tion on information asymmetry issues (e.g., Aggarwal & Yousef, 2000; Ahmed, 2002; Haque &
Mirakhor, 1986; Khalil, Rickwood, & Murinde, 2002), which is in contradiction with otherstheoreti-
cal contributions that show an excellent capacity of sharing contracts to reduce information asymme-
try (e.g., Al-Suwailem, 2003; Presley & Sessions, 1994; Stiglitz, 1974).
Thus, while dominance of markup contracts is an obvious fact, its theoretical explanation remains
ambiguous. Our paper reviews the information asymmetry considerations in an attempt to reconcile
the two previous positions. Despite the similar nature of information asymmetries inherent in sharing
and markup contracts, coexistence of these two contractual categories in the same market is impeded
by a dual pricing that produces an additional (or artificial) dimension of adverse selection.
Moreover, we propose specialised use of two Islamic contractual categories as a device for
eliminating artificial adverse selection. Furthermore, this specialisation allows to calculateon the
basis of financing cost unificationan endogenous markup, that is independently of the interest
rate. However, we have to make clear that financing cost unification does not mean that each
1
Including banks, companies and investment funds.
2
On the Iranian market, mudharaba and musharaka together represented 26% of all financing contracts in 1995 and just 16%
in 1998 against 45% of credit sales (including murabaha) in 1995 and 56% in 1998.
DOI: 10.1111/twec.12510
738
|
©2017 John Wiley & Sons Ltd wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/twec World Econ. 2018;41:738751.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT