Shareholder coordination and corporate innovation

AuthorAni Manakyan Mathers,Xiaohong (Sara) Wang,Bin Wang
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jbfa.12433
Date01 May 2020
Published date01 May 2020
DOI: 10.1111/jbfa.12433
Shareholder coordination and corporate
innovation
Ani Manakyan Mathers1Bin Wang2Xiaohong (Sara) Wang3
1Department of Economics and Finance, Perdue
School of Business, Salisbury University,
Salisbury, MD, 21801, USA
2Department of Finance, College of Business
Administration,Marquette University,
Milwaukee,WI, 53210, USA
3Department of Accounting, Business Law and
Finance, College of Business and Management,
Northeastern Illinois University, Chicago, IL,
60625, USA
Correspondence
BinWang, Department of Finance, College of
BusinessAdministration, Marquette University,
Milwaukee,WI 53210, USA.
Email:bin.wang@marquette.edu
Fundinginformation
FranklinP.Perdue School of Business
[Correctionadded on 4 March 2020, after first
onlinepublication: The acknowledgements
sectionhas been updated to include funding
details.]
Abstract
We show that greater shareholder coordination, as proxied by the
geographic proximity between institutional investors, is positively
related to corporateinnovation outcomes. This relationship is driven
by coordination among dedicated and independent institutions who
have strong monitoring incentives and is more pronounced among
firms with lower blockholder ownership and greater information
asymmetry where there is greater benefit to monitoring. We pro-
pose that shareholder coordination promotes corporate innovation
through a reduction in managerial agency problems. Overall, our
results are consistent with the notion that greater shareholder coor-
dination enables diffuse shareholders to monitor managers more
effectively and enhances corporate innovation.
KEYWORDS
agency problem, Innovation, monitoring, shareholder coordination
JEL CLASSIFICATION
O30, G34
1INTRODUCTION
Innovation is a key driverof economic growth. However, market frictions may hinder innovation. A fear of being fired
due to bad luck under uncertain investment outcomes (Holmstrom, 1999), the private benefits of effort shirking and
avoiding difficult tasks (Hart, 1983), and a focus on short-term stock price (Stein, 1988, 1989) may hinder managers
from innovating. Several studies suggest that the presence of institutional investors helps to alleviate this underin-
vestment problem. For example, Aghion, Van Reenen, and Zingales (2013) find that greateri nstitutional ownership
increases innovation productivity. Edmans (2009) contends that equity blockholders can gather private information
about firms’ fundamental value and utilize their exit option to pressure managers to make optimal innovation deci-
sions. Bushee (1998) provides evidence that firm managers are less likely to cut investmentin research and develop-
ment (R&D) to makeup for an earnings decline when there is greater institutional ownership.
Nonetheless, the literature has largely ignored the fact that institutional ownership is often diffuse in prac-
tice. Huang (2014) documents that between 1980 and 2011 the median institution’s equity holding accounts
for only 0.06% of the firm’s total outstanding shares, and the dispersion of ownership has increased over time.
730 c
2020 John Wiley & Sons Ltd wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jbfa JBus Fin Acc. 2020;47:730–759.
MATHERSET AL.731
The diffusion of ownership gives rise to the classical free rider problem (Grossman & Hart, 1980) and potentially
weakens the monitoring efforts of institutional investors. This free rider problem may be more acute in the case
of monitoring innovation productivity, where monitoring costs are greater due to the high uncertainty of innova-
tion outcomes and the hard-to-verify private information and actions of managers (e.g., Fuente & Marin, 1996).1
However, if diffuse institutions are able to coordinate their monitoring efforts and share the gains of monitor-
ing, then they may act like a large blockholder and exert greater pressure on management, resulting in improved
corporate governance and better innovation outcomes.2For example, institutional investors may collaborate
to improve managers’ incentive to innovate by monitoring the managers collectively and protecting them from
being fired due to purely bad luck in innovation outcomes. Coordinated institutional investors may also force
managers to exert costly effort to innovate and to focus less on short-term stock prices but more on value-
increasing long-term innovation projects through enhanced monitoring, such as the threat of collectively selling their
shares.
We empirically examine whether firms with a greater presence of coordinated shareholders have greater inno-
vation productivity. Following the literature(e.g., Coval & Moskowitz, 2001; Huang, 2014), we measure shareholder
coordination based on the geographic proximity of a firm’s institutional investors. Our proxy for shareholder coor-
dination builds upon the social network literature, which suggests that social networks are more likely to develop
when individuals are able to associate and bond with others due to familiarity, often driven by geographicproximity
(e.g., Marsden, 1988; McPherson, Smith-Lovin, & Cook, 2001). Institutional investors who work in the same region
are more likely to share similar cultural values and to have repeated social interactions, for example at local invest-
ment conferences, which foster familiarity and mutual trust for cooperation and information sharing. The existing
literature also suggests that geographic proximity is influential in building close personal and business relationships.
For example, Hong, Kubik, and Stein (2005) show that geographic proximity promotes word-of-mouth communica-
tions between mutual fund managers and leads to similar trading decisions among managers in the same city.3There-
fore, we contend that shareholders with closer geographic proximity are more likely to coordinate their monitoring
efforts.
We find that firms with more coordinated institutional investorshave greater innovation productivity, as measured
by patent counts and patent citations. These findings are driven by coordination between institutional investors with
stronger monitoring incentives. Specifically, we find that innovation is only positively associated with coordination
among dedicated institutions with a long-term investment horizon (Bushee, 1998) and independent investors with
no business relationship with the firm (Chen, Harford, & Li, 2007) and unrelated to the presence of geographically
proximate institutions with short-term investment horizons or potential business relationships with the firm. To
address potential endogeneity concerns, we conduct a series of tests. We implement a two-stage residual analysis to
alleviate concerns that shareholder coordination may simply be an aggregate measure of other firm characteristics,
such as institutional ownership or analyst coverage.We find that the unexplained portion of shareholder coordination
is significantly and positively associated with patent counts and citations, suggesting that shareholder coordination
is an important incremental factor beyond determinants of innovation previously documented in the literature.
Reverse causality may also be a concern if institutional investors with a preference to invest in innovative firms
are clustered in certain geographic areas. To address this issue, we use a generalized method of moments (GMM)
1Studiesshow that investments in innovation have a failure rate between 50%–80% (Asplund & Sandin, 1999; Cozjinsen, Vrakking, & IJerzloo, 2000).
2Anecdotalevidence suggests that institutional investors often engage in collaborative actions. Forinstance, the California S tate Teacher’sRetirement System
(CALSTRS) partnered with California-based Relational Investors LLCto force Occidental Petroleum to improve its corporate governance practices and to
push the TimkenCompany to spin off its steel division (CALSTRS, 2010, 2013). Research also shows that institutional investors can work together to initiate
shareholderproposals to influence corporate decisions (e.g., Gillan & Starks, 2000).
3Specifically, Hong et al. (2005) show that mutual fund managers are more likelyto buy (or sell) a particular stock if other managers in the same city are
buying(or selling) that same stock. Geographic proximity has also been shown to be an important determinant of friendship and marriage (Bossard, 1932), the
formation of interlocked corporateboards (Kono, Palmer, Friedland, & Zafonte, 1998), the development of relationships among floor traders (Baker,1984),
andventure capital firms’ investment decisions (Sorenson & Stuart, 2001).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT