Set them (almost) free: Discretion in electoral campaigns under incomplete information

Date01 August 2019
AuthorElena Manzoni,Vardan Baghdasaryan
Published date01 August 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12363
Received: 2 January 2018
|
Revised: 10 September 2018
|
Accepted: 17 January 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12363
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Set them (almost) free: Discretion in electoral
campaigns under incomplete information
Vardan Baghdasaryan
1,2
|
Elena Manzoni
3
1
College of Business and Economics,
American University of Armenia, Yerevan,
Armenia
2
CERGEEI Foundation, Prague, Czech
Republic
3
Department of Economics, University of
Verona, Verona, Italy
Correspondence
Elena Manzoni, Department of Economics,
University of Verona, via Cantarane 24,
37129, Verona, Italy.
Email: elena.manzoni@univr.it
Abstract
The paper analyzes a model of electoral campaigning as a
problem of competitive delegation. We consider an environ-
ment characterized by two sources of uncertainty: uncer-
tainty on the nature of the optimal policy and uncertainty on
the candidatesbiases. Although voters know whether the
candidate is leftor rightwing, they do not know the extent
of the bias. In this environment, discretion may benefit
voters as it allows the elected politician to adjust his policies
to the state of the world. The paper shows that the optimal
set of promises must be a closed interval, whose size is
decreasing in the expected bias of the candidate. An
example where the set of types is finite shows that an
increase in the variability of candidatestypes may either
increase or decrease the voterswillingness to grant
discretion to politicians.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
First: the reduction of the fiscal burden with total exemption for incomes up to 22 million of Italian
liras per year; the reduction of the tax rate for incomes up to 200 million to 23%; the reduction of
the tax rate for incomes above 200 million to 33%.
1
(S. Berlusconi, 2001)
“… our first promise is that we will not steal money from the Italians and that we will reduce the
fiscal burden below 40% of the GDP.
2
(S. Berlusconi, 2008)
J Public Econ Theory. 2019;21:622649.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet622
|
© 2019 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
1
In the original language: Punto primo: Abbattimento della pressione fiscale con lesenzione totale dei redditi fino a 22 milioni di lire annui; riduzione al
23 per cento dellaliquota per i redditi fino a 200 milioni; riduzione al 33 per cento dellaliquota per i redditi sopra i 200 milioni.From Corriere della Sera,
online version, March 3, 2008.
2
In the original language: “… la nostra prima promessa è che non metteremo mai le mani nelle tasche degli italiani e che abbasseremo la pressione fiscale
sotto il 40% del Pil.From Corriere della Sera, online version, February 29, 2008.
What we need is a decisive government that says we are going to have a budget that will help small
businesses like the ones here with a cut in Corporation Tax, saying that any new business doesnt
have to pay National Insurance on the first ten new jobs, busting open state procurement so you can
all bid for the state contracts, and make sure that you can make money for your businesses out of
what the government does.
3
(D. Cameron, 2010)
I want to make it absolutely crystal clear that our objective when the fiscal circumstances are right,
is to lower all taxes. We want to lower all taxes. We really are the party of lower, simpler, fairer
taxeslook at our record in government.
4
(T. Abbott, 2013)
Vagueness of electoral campaign statements is a common element of political elections, experienced by voters
of every country and political arena. As the abovementioned examples show, political announcements during the
electoral campaign may have different degrees of vagueness, therefore leaving different degrees of postelectoral
freedom to elected politicians.
The issue of vagueness in electoral campaigns has attracted considerable interest in the economic and political
science literature. In most cases, the phenomenon is described as a candidatedriven phenomenon in which
politicians are able to maintain discretionality despite facing ambiguityaverse voters.
5
There is, however,
increasing evidence that ambiguity can, in fact, be supported by voters (Hersh and Schaffner, 2013; Tomz and Van
Houweling, 2009). Although candidates have a clear interest in conducting an electoral campaign that guarantees
the possibility of choosing their preferred policy expost, voterspreferences for a vague politician are less obvious.
This paper provides a rationale for this type of voterspreferences and investigates whether and how incomplete
information on candidatespolicy preferences may affect the discretionality of the policy announcements.
We introduce a model in which ambiguity of the electoral promises results from a delegation objective:
depending on how changing the environment is, the tension between control and discretion that the electorate
experiences may be resolved with voters having a preference for some degree of discretion. Specifically, voters may
prefer to elect a politician with a political program that leaves him free to operate in a given policy region once
elected, targeting the policy to the state of the world expost. Notably, this result holds true even when voters do
not know the candidates bias. In particular, the level of discretion that the voters are willing to concede to the
candidates is inversely related to their expected bias (where the bias is defined with respect to the median voters
preferences). In the main model, the type structure is such that the variability and the expectation of the bias are
interlinked. Therefore, we introduce an example with a discretetype structure, which allows for a comparative
statics analysis on the variability of the bias for a given level of expected bias. The relation between the level of
discretion and the uncertainty over the candidatestypes varies depending on the values of the parameters; in
some parametric regions, an increase in the uncertainty over the candidates types decreases the level of discretion
that the voters are willing to leave, as one would expect given that the voters are riskaverse. In other parametric
regions, however, the effect is the opposite and more uncertainty implies more discretion for the candidates; this is
due to an insurance effect that the bounds of the set of promises exert: increasing the upper or lower bound
(depending on whether the candidate is rightwing or leftwing) has the effect of giving more discretion to good
candidatestypes, and not so much to bad candidatestypes, who will hit the bound more often and will be
constrained by it anyway.
The paper contributes to different strands of literature. First of all, we relate to the extensive theoretical
literature on ambiguity in electoral campaigns that started with Shepsle (1972) and Page (1976). The literature
discusses quite diverse reasons that may give rise to ambiguity in electoral campaigns. A strand of the literature
3
http://conservativespeeches.sayit.mysociety.org/speech/601487
4
http://www.abc.net.au/news/20140501/ factfilewhattonyabbottpromisedontax/5420226
5
See, among others, Alesina and Cuckierman (1990), Alesina and Holden (2008), Aragones and Neeman (2000), Glazer (1990), and Meirowitz (2005).
BAGHDASARYAN AND MANZONI
|
623

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT