Sequential procurement auctions and their effect on investment decisions

AuthorNicolás Figueroa,Gonzalo Cisternas
Date01 October 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12112
Published date01 October 2015
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.46, No. 4, Winter 2015
pp. 824–843
Sequential procurement auctions and their
effect on investment decisions
Gonzalo Cisternas
and
Nicol´
as Figueroa∗∗
We characterize the optimal mechanism and investment level in an environment where (i) two
projects of independent costs are purchased sequentially, (ii) the buyer can commit to a two-
period mechanism, and (iii) the winner of the first project can investin a cost-reducing technology
between auctions. We show that, in an attempt to induce more competition in the first period,
the optimal mechanism gives an advantage to the first-period winner in the second auction. As
a result of this advantage, the first-period winner invests more than the socially efficient level.
Optimal advantages, therefore, create two different channels for cost minimization in buyer-
supplier relationships.
1. Introduction
Managing relationships with suppliers is critical to the success of many firms. To achieve
low procurement costs, a buyer maywant to encourage competition among suppliers, but she may
also hope that suppliers make investments that lower their costs of production. Two extreme views
appear. The arm’s-length model—prevalent in the United States—promotes competition in every
period to strengthen a buyer’s bargaining power (Porter, 1985). The partnership model—adopted
in some Japanese industries—instead fosters long-term relationships by awarding advantages to
suppliers with records of good performance; in return, these suppliers invest in specific assets
that can reduce production costs.1
In this article, we ask how the desires to promote competition and, at the same time, to
encourage relationship-specific investments, may be best balanced to minimize a buyer’s cost of
procurement. Using the mechanism-design approach, we show that advantages to incumbents
can optimally arise in fully competitive environments characterized by the repeated interaction
Massachusetts Institute of Technology; gcistern@mit.edu.
∗∗Pontificia Universidad Cat´
olica de Chile; nicolasf@uc.cl.
We are especially grateful to Soledad Arellano, Leandro Arozamena, Alessandro Bonatti, Vinicius Carrasco, H´
ector
Chade, Bob Gibbons, Heikki Rantakari, and Mike Whinston for their valuable feedback on this article. We would also
like to thank the Editor, David Martimort, and an anonymous referee for very thoughtful comments. Figueroa was
partially supported by the Complex Engineering Systems Institute, Millennium Nucleus Information and Coordination
in Networks ICM/FIC RC130003, and by Fondecytgrant no. 1141124.
1See Dyer (1994) and Dyer, Cho, and Chu (1998) for evidencefrom the Japanese automobile industry.
824 C2015, The RAND Corporation.
SEQUENTIAL PROCUREMENT AUCTIONS AND THEIR EFFECT / 825
between a buyer and multiple sellers. Even more so, we show that these advantages can generate
strong incentives to invest in cost reduction. In dynamic settings, therefore, contracts that lie in
between the arm’s-length and partnership models can have a critical impact on the long-term cost
structure of suppliers.
In our model, a buyer must purchase two projects sequentially from a pool of potential
sellers. The sellers’ costs for performing both tasks are distributed independently across time and
across competitors, and they are private information to each firm. We assume that the first-period
winner can improve his cost distribution for the second competition by undertaking a costly
investment between auctions. This decision can be observable (and contractible) or not. In this
context, we characterize (i) the cost-minimizing mechanism chosen by a seller with commitment
power and (ii) the investment level carried out by the first-period winner. Because the return
from investing in a better technology depends on how the second-period mechanism treats the
first-period winner, the final degree of asymmetry between sellers is determined endogenously
by the optimal mechanism.
Our model fits many real-world examples of repeated buyer-supplier interactions in which
winning bidders have the possibility to invest to reduce their costs, or to improve the value
of the goods offered to the buyer. In the car industry, for example, there is vast evidence that
suppliers that win a contract in this industry get to better understand the manufacturers’ needs,
which allows for investments that better tailor products to the specific needs of the purchaser
(Richardson, 1993). A similar phenomenon takes place in spectrum auctions, where firms that
develop significant market positions investin their brand name and in their knowledge about their
customer base, thus developing a higher valuation for frequencies in future sales (Klemperer,
2004). In all these settings, the buyer faces an important choice. Should she promote competition
in every period to obtain lower prices? Alternatively, should she, instead, give an advantage to a
previous winner to foster investments that will eventually result in lower prices?
Although in practice all sellers have the potential to improve their technologies, there are
many instances in which significant investments take place only after becoming an established
provider. In the defense industry, for instance, technological capabilities developed through
learning-by-doing play a key role in shaping a seller’s cost structure. Winners of previous auc-
tions thus have a natural advantage over losers, as developing a final product provides them with
information that is unavailable to those sellers that stop at the design stage. A similar phenomenon
occurs in purchases that involve sellers making relationship-specific investments. Dyer (1994,
1996) documents that suppliers of Toyota and Chrysler undertook important relationship-specific
investments (manufacturer-specific software, human capital, proximity to plants, etc.) after be-
coming well-established providersto each firm.2It is often the case that these types of investments
are prohibitively costly for those sellers who are not currently serving the buyer. Alternatively,
sellers who have not been awarded previous contracts may lack the necessary information to
identify which types of investments effectively add value to the relationship.
As a benchmark, we first consider the ex post efficient mechanism: in each period,the project
is assigned to the lowest-cost supplier,and the efficient level of investment optimally balances the
cost of this decision with the benefit of having a better competitor when the efficient allocation
rule is in place. In this case, we show that the planner’s and the winner’s investment incentivesare
aligned. Consequently, the socially efficient level of investment can be implemented using two
second-price procurement auctions.
Wethen use the mechanism-design approach to characterize the cost-minimizing mechanism
under incentive constraints. When the buyer is able to commit to a two-period mechanism, we
show that the optimal mechanism gives an advantage to the first-period winner in the second
auction: it awards him the project, even in some cases in which his cost is larger than the cost of
other competitors. The reasoning is as follows. In the setting we study, the buyer cannot commit
2Investmentsin plant proximity also take place in the case of contracts for the distribution of school meals in Chile,
as winners build infrastructure in different regions of the country (Olivares et al., 2011).
C
The RAND Corporation 2015.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT