Selective incentives and intragroup heterogeneity in collective contests

AuthorShmuel Nitzan,Kaoru Ueda
Published date01 August 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12290
Date01 August 2018
Received: 23 July 2017 Accepted: 16 January 2018
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12290
ARTICLE
Selective incentives and intragroup heterogeneity
in collective contests
Shmuel Nitzan1Kaoru Ueda2
1Departmentof Economics, Bar Ilan University,
Israeland Hitotsubashi Institute of Advanced
Study,Hitotsubashi University
2Facultyof Economics, Nanzan University
ShmuelNitzan, Department of Economics, Bar
IlanUniversity, Ramat Gan, 52900 Israel and
HitotsubashiInstitute of Advanced Study, Hitot-
subashiUniversity, 186-8601 Tokyo,Kunitachi,
Naka,Japan (nitzans@mail.biu.ac.il). Kaoru Ueda,
Facultyof Economics, Nanzan University, Nagoya,
Aichi466-0824, Japan (k-ueda@nanzan-u.ac.jp)
Theauthors are indebted to three anonymous ref-
ereesfor their useful comments and suggestions.
Uedaacknowledges the financial support of JSPS
KAKENHIGrant Number JP17K03781.
A group taking part in a contest has to confront the collective action
problem among its members, and devices of selective incentives are
possible means of resolution. We argue that heterogeneous prize-
valuations in a competing group normally prevent effective use of
such selective incentives. Tosubstantiate this claim, we adopt cost-
sharing as a means of incentivizing the individual group members.
Weconfirm that homogeneous prize valuations within a group result
in a cost-sharing rule inducing the first-best individual contributions.
As long as the cost-sharing rule is dependent only on the members’
contributions, however, such a first-best rule does not exist for a
group with intragroup heterogeneity. Our main result clarifies how
unequal prize valuations affect the cost-sharing rule and, in partic-
ular, the degree of cost-sharing. If the relative rateof change of the
marginal effort costs is decreasing, it is reduced by intragroup het-
erogeneity.If the rate is increasing, the cost is fully shared, but it can-
not induce the first-best contributions for the group.
1INTRODUCTION
In a collective contest the contestants for a prize are groups. Applications of such contests include confrontations
between labor unions and the employers, ethnic or religious conflicts, military conflict between countries or allies of
countries, promotional competitions by firms with marketing activities, a championship by sports teams, competition
among academic institutes on quality-based recognition or on financial support, and so on.1This paper examines how
heterogeneity of individuals in a group affects the incentive device in such a contest.
Usually a group contains various individuals situated at different positions, politically,economically, and sometimes
ethnically or culturally. Such heterogeneity could prevent them from reaching a consensus on the value of the con-
tested prize, and they naturally havedifferent prize valuations. Their contributions to the contest are diversified then,
which could be inefficient for the group as a whole. Intragroup heterogeneity of competing groups is not an old topic in
the literature of collectivecontests. Baik (2008) examines a model of collective contests for group-specific public-good
prize, assuming linear cost functions, that is, constant marginal costs. Esteban and Ray (2011) study a model of ethnic
conflict with two parameters of intragroup heterogeneity: ethnic radicalism and income. Epstein and Mealem (2009)
and Ryvkin (2011) examine how the composition of individuals in competing groups affects the equilibrium effort
1Formore examples of contests in general, see Konrad (2009). On the basic theory of contests, see Hillman and Riley (1989) and Cornes and Hartley (2005).
Journal of Public Economic Theory.2018;20:477–498. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet c
2018 Wiley Periodicals,Inc. 477
478 NITZAN AND UEDA
levels. Nitzan and Ueda (2013) clarify how the form of effort cost functions determines the relation between intra-
group heterogeneity and the equilibrium group effort. Most of the existing literature, however,ignores the possibility
that a competing group introduces an incentive device.
When individuals win or lose the prize as a group, they work as a team sharing a common aim. In such a situa-
tion, the individuals are usually tempted to be free-riders while considering contribution to the teamwork to enhance
the group winning probability.This tendency results in a representative collective action problem, as argued by Olson
(1965,1982).2Collective contests could be viewed as a number of intragroup collective action problems embedded in a
competitive environment. Olson argues that the collectiveaction problem can be amended by “selective incentives,”—
incentives applied selectively to individuals depending on their actions.3In the literature on collective contests, such
an incentive device has been incorporated into the model typically as a prize-sharing rule of a group, which prescribes
how much of the won prize is distributed according to the contributions by the group members.4Choosing an ade-
quate prize-sharing rule prior to the contest, individuals in a group could be effectively motivated to overcome the
free-rider problem. Nitzan and Ueda (2011) consider such a model of a collective contest in which the prize-sharing
rule in each group is endogenously determined to maximize the utilitarian group welfare (i.e., the sum of the expected
utility of the group members), and derive the result that every group can realize the collectivelyoptimal contributions
by its members in a consistent way with the group's objective. The individuals in a group are, however,assumed to be
homogeneous; they havethe same valuation of the prize and the form of their effort cost function is also the same.
Groupsin a real world are characterized by intragroup heterogeneity, to a great or small extent. When competing for
a prize, they face at least two sources of inefficiency,free riding and individual heterogeneity. The selective incentive
devices chosen by the groups must cope with these sources of inefficiency. To make the effect of intragroup hetero-
geneity explicit is therefore important to understand the properties of the appropriate selective incentive devices to
be adopted in collective contests. Forthis purpose, we use a modified model of Nitzan and Ueda (2011) containing two
new important features.
The first is, of course, the existence of intragroup heterogeneity.Unfortunately, however,it is not easy to analyze a
model of prize-sharing with intragroup heterogeneity and, in particular,to characterize the equilibrium prize-sharing
rules. It is especially so when the effort cost of an individual is nonlinear, and such nonlinearity is essential to get
general insights on the collective-contest problem.5Therefore, a second new feature is introduced; instead of prize-
sharing rules, our model assumes that the competing groups use cost-sharing rules as a means of selective incentives.
It has been recently pointed out by Vázquez (2017) that commitment to a transfer rule of the costs among individual
group members can work as a substitute for a prize-sharing rule. Actually,once we notice that cost-sharing makes the
resources of the individuals in a group a common pool resource, it is not surprising that such a device enhances their
activity levels. In general,transfer schemes within a group depending on the sacrifice to enhance the common interest
can work as selective incentives. An individual who contributes more can shift more cost to the others relative to the
2As similar concepts to free-riding, we could count shirking and social loafing (Kidwell and Bennett, 1993). The former is a term used in the context of the
economics of organization, and the latter is mainly used in studies of social psychology.All three concepts concern individuals withholding effort in a group.
Suchoverlapping of concepts in the different areas stresses the substantial role played by the free riding problem in determining the performance of a group.
3Olson's severalconjectures on the collective action problems are neatly arranged and evaluated by Sandler (1992). For two recent surveys on the develop-
mentof research on collective action problems, see Pecorino (2015) and Sandler (2015).
4The idea of a prize-sharing rule is introduced to the research on collective contests by Nitzan (1991). Baik (1994), S. Lee (1995), and Ueda (2002) develop
modelsin which the prize sharing rule is endogenously determined by each of the competing groups. It should be noted that higher selective incentives are not
necessarilybetter for a group. When the members are rewarded for their effort, each member's effort has a negative externality for the others because their
sharesare cut. The result might be an excessive group effort. See Sen (1966).
5Severalimpressive results derived from contest models with linear effort costs are not necessarily preserved under non-linear cost functions. For example,
Estebana nd Ray(2001) reveal that collective contests for a pure private-good prize with linear effort cost functions belong to a special case where the group
size paradoxis always obtained, that is, a smaller group attains a higher win probability. They prove that the paradoxis overturned if the elasticity of marginal
effortcosts is large. Another puzzling possibility is that an individual with a higher prize valuation can get a lower expected payoff in a group (it could be called a
strongversion of the “exploitation of the great by the small”). This is a normal case in contests with linear effort costs, unless the largest value of the valuations
is very prominent. The reason is, as shown by Baik (2008), that in this case only individuals with the largest valuation of the prize in a group put effort,and
all the other group members become pure free riders (see also D.Lee [2012] for interesting related results). But Nitzan and Ueda (2013) point out that such
exploitation is impossible if the elasticity of marginal effort costs is large. We will present another exampleof the peculiarity of the model with linear cost
functionsin Section 5.2. These examples imply that we should be careful regarding the robustness of the results obtained under linear costs.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT