Scale versus scope in the diffusion of new technology: evidence from the farm tractor

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12230
Published date01 June 2018
AuthorDaniel P. Gross
Date01 June 2018
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.49, No. 2, Summer 2018
pp. 427–452
Scale versus scope in the diffusion of new
technology: evidence from the farm tractor
Daniel P. Gross
Although tractors are nowused in nearly every agricultural field operation and in the production
of nearly all crops, they first developed with much more limited application. Early diffusion was
accordingly rapid in these narrower applications but limited in scope until tractor technology
generalized. The sequence of diffusion is consistent with a model of Research and Development
(R&D) in specific- versus general-purpose attributes and with other historical examples, sug-
gesting that the key to understanding technology diffusion lies not only in explaining the number
of different users, but also in explaining the number of different uses.
1. Introduction
Technology diffusion is widely viewed as a leading explanation for productivity growth
and productivity differences across industries, firms, and geographic regions. For example, it is
frequently argued that facilitating the diffusion of modern production technologies to manufac-
turing and agriculture in developing countries is a key to lifting incomes and breaking a cycle
of poverty. More generally, diffusion is typically viewed as the fastest path to the technology
frontier. Research on technology diffusionhas made significant inroads in explaining variation in
its scale, treating as fixed the total potential market. Considerably less attention has been paid to
changes in scope—the set of potential applications, and thus the size of the market itself—despite
that this extensive margin is one of the principal dimensions along which technologies spread.1
Harvard University and NBER; dgross@hbs.edu.
I am grateful to Barry Eichengreen for his support in this project. I also thank Dominick Bartelme, Carola Binder, Susan
Carter, Brad DeLong, Alex Field, Joel Mokyr, Petra Moser, Alan Olmstead,Mar tha Olney, Paul Rhode, Daniel Robert,
Richard Sutch, Noam Yuchtman,and the Editor and referees for helpful comments and suggestions, as well as participants
in the BEHL Economic History Lunch, All-UC Hundred Flowers conference, and NBER DAE Summer Institute poster
session. I am grateful to Richard Sutch for sharing data on hybrid corn diffusion from the USDA Agricultural Statistics. I
thank the BerkeleyEconomic Histor y Lab and All-UC Group in Economic History for financial support. This research was
additionally supported by NSF Graduate Research FellowshipGrant no. DGE-1106400 and an EHA Graduate Fellowship.
The appendices referenced in this article are available online at www.dpgross.com/.All errors are my own.
1As Griliches (1957) shows, logistic models of technology diffusion are parametrized by (i) whenit begins, and
(ii) the rate at which it proceeds. These two parameters characterize what I refer to in this article as “scope” and “scale,”
respectively. Research on diffusion has overwhelmingly focused attention on the latter, which has been attributed to
heterogeneous costs and benefits (Duflo, Kremer, and Robinson, 2008; Suri, 2011), fixedcosts of adopting an indivisible
technology (David,1966; Olmstead, 1975), and changes in relative factor prices (Manuelli and Seshadri, 2014), as well as
C2018, The RAND Corporation. 427
428 / THE RAND JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
This article shows that the historical diffusion of farm tractors—a technology which revo-
lutionized 20th-century crop production and is a fixture in modern agriculture—was the result
of not only an increasing number of users, but also a growing number of uses. The tractor first
developed for narrow applications with existing complementary equipment, exogenously high
demand, and relatively lower R&D costs, and initial diffusion was accordingly rapid for these
applications, but otherwise limited in scope. Only later did tractor technology become sufficiently
general in purpose for its diffusion to be broad based and pervasive. This pattern of expanding
scope is consistent with other historical examples and with economic theory, which suggests
that in this context, R&D will naturally progress from specific- to general-purpose variants of
an innovation, and that these technical advances will (i) drive the development of additional
complementary technologies, and (ii) and directly translate to an increasing scope of diffusion.
Lags in diffusion can therefore be the result of hold-ups and market failures in R&D that stymie
the generalization of existing technology.
The article opens by reviewing the history of the farm tractor. Here, it is useful to first clarify
what the tractor is: farm tractors are vehicles that tow and powerthe ag ricultural implements that
do the day-to-day workof plowing, planting, cultivating, and harvesting crops. Though now used
in nearly every agricultural field operation and in the production of nearly all crops, tractors first
developed for use in tillage and harvesting grain. Early, fixed-tread models could not navigate
row crops without destroyingthe crop, and this generation of tractor technology was therefore not
a candidate to replace draft power on corn-growing farms at any price. By the 1930s, however,
a more versatile, general-purpose design had emerged, making it possible for these farms to
“replace their horses and mules with one general-purpose tractor” (Sanders, 2009).
The era of the tractor in US agriculture begins in the late 1910s, prior to which diffusion was
effectively zero. Using serial numbers and production data from the four major manufacturers of
this period, I first verify that fixed-tread models dominated tractor production up until the early
1930s, accounting for 96% of tractors manufactured from 1917 to 1928, and 91% through 1932.
During the 1930s, the industry made a near-complete transition to general-purpose models, which
comprised over 85% of units produced between 1933 and 1940.
I then use county-level data from the US Census of Agriculture to show that the initial wave
of tractor diffusion in the 1920s was concentrated in the Wheat Belt states of North Dakota, South
Dakota, and Kansas, whereas a second wavefrom 1930 to 1940 was concentrated in the Corn Belt
states of Iowa, Illinois, and Nebraska. This sequence is plainly visible in maps of wheat versus
corn intensity and diffusion (Figure 1). Numerically, I find that county-level diffusion from 1925
to 1930 was 0.4 percentage points greater with every percent of farmland in wheat but did not
vary with farmland in corn. From 1930 to 1940, the pattern is precisely reversed, following the
introduction of the general-purpose tractor and mechanical corn harvestor; in the 1940s, diffusion
rounds out in counties with little of either crop and primarily growing hay. The results are robust
to a wide variety of controls, sample restrictions, and definitions of diffusion—establishing that
they are not due to changes in farm sizes, local factor prices, financial conditions, dealer networks,
New Deal relief, the Dust Bowl, the contemporaneous diffusion of hybrid corn, or other features
of Midwest agriculture that might have affected tractor demand in this period.
The question remains as to why the tractor’s development followed this sequence. To put
structure around this phenomenon, I introduce a model of innovation where a firm develops a
technology with application-specific and general-purpose technological attributes, and where the
value of the innovation depends on the evolving quality of complementary technologies. The
model borrows ideas from the framework developed by Bresnahan and Trajtenberg (1995) to
characterize general-purpose technologies, while endogenizing the path of product development.
Intuitively, this model suggests that product features develop in the order in which they are most
valuable, implyingthat new technologies will often first be invented for narrow applications where
to suboptimal decision-making due to credit constraints (Clarke, 1991), information spillovers (Conley and Udry,2010;
Dupas, 2014; Munshi, 2004), and individual biases (Duflo, Kremer, and Robinson, 2011).
C
The RAND Corporation 2018.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT