Saving the public from the private? Incentives and outcomes in dual practice

Date01 August 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12447
AuthorRobert Nuscheler,Michael Kuhn
Published date01 August 2020
J Public Econ Theory. 2020;22:11201150.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet1120
|
© 2020 Wiley Periodicals LLC
Received: 28 May 2019
|
Accepted: 17 April 2020
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12447
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Saving the public from the private? Incentives
and outcomes in dual practice
Michael Kuhn
1
|Robert Nuscheler
2
1
Wittgenstein Centre (Univ. Vienna, IIASA,
VID/ÖAW), Vienna Institute of
Demography, Vienna, Austria
2
Faculty of Business and Economics,
University of Augsburg, Augsburg,
Germany
Correspondence
Robert Nuscheler, Faculty of Business and
Economics, University of Augsburg,
Universitätsstr. 16, 86159 Augsburg,
Germany.
Email: robert.nuscheler@wiwi.uni-
augsburg.de
Abstract
We consider a monopoly physician offering free
public treatment and, if allowed, a private treat-
ment for which patients have to pay out of pocket.
While patients differ in the propensity to benefit
from private treatment it always yields better
health outcomes than public treatment but is also
more costly in terms of money and time. We study
the physician's supply of private care and allocation
of time costs across public and private patients and
contrast these with the firstbest allocation. To in-
crease the willingnesstopay for private treatment
the physician shifts time costs to public patients.
While this turns out to be socially optimal, the re-
sulting positive network effect leads to an over
provision of private care if time costs are suffi-
ciently high. A secondbest allocation arises when
the health authority sets public reimbursement but
has no control over private provision. Depending
on the welfare weight the health authority attaches
to physician profits, a ban of dual practice may
improve on the secondbest allocation. Notably, a
ban benefits not only public patients but also
private patients with a moderate propensity to
benefit from private care.
1|INTRODUCTION
The provision of health services of both a public and private nature by one and the same
provider, typically labeled dual practice, is a common yet strongly contested arrangement
within many health care systems.
1
Generally, dual practice is an arrangement that admits the
inflow of additional private resources into a public sector that is subject to more or less severe
resource constraints. In a number of countries with a national health service, such as the United
Kingdom or Southern European countries, the provision of treatments (e.g., surgery) within
private practice is allowed as a means to reduce public sector waiting times (e.g., Barros &
Olivella, 2005; Gonzalez, 2005; Iversen, 1997). The idea is that the profit incentive from private
practice may stimulate additional treatment effort so that total waiting time is reduced to the
benefit of even those patients who are not prioritized and remain on the public waiting list.
However, such an arrangement may be plagued by creamskimming (Barros & Olivella, 2005;
Gonzalez, 2005) and the incentive to manipulate upwards public waiting times to stimulate
private demand (Iversen, 1997). A second argument as to why dual practice may contribute to
relieving funding pressures within a public health sector is provided by Bir and Eggleston (2003)
and Eggleston and Bir (2006) who argue that the additional income (and perhaps professional
satisfaction) from private practice helps to attract highly skilled personnel into the public health
sector even at comparatively low levels of public reimbursement.
A third argument relates to dual practice as a vehicle to allow for the provision of additional
and/or higher quality services which are not included in public health care plans but may
nevertheless be valued by some patients (e.g., Biglaiser & Ma, 2007; Brekke & Sørgard, 2007).
Indeed, funding pressures within the public health care system force more and more funding
agents (governments or health insurers) to restrict services to a basic bundle.Additional
services, which may be valuable to some individuals but do not prove costeffective for the
whole population, may then be purchased on the private market. In Germany, for instance,
such arrangements are already in place for dentistry, where many intensive treatments have
been excluded from statutory health insurance and deferred to a private market (possibly
private insurance). Similar arrangements apply to the services of ambulatory care physicians in
Austria, where certain treatments are exempt from statutory health insurance or subject to
considerable copayments with patients having an option to purchase private topup insurance.
Finally, within secondary care, in many countries such as Austria and Germany public patients
do not typically have a statutory right to be treated by senior consultants, but such an option
may be purchased privately. In light of increasing pressures on public health care budgets
triggered, for example, by the aging of populations, we would expect a rather general and far
reaching shift in health care finance towards a mix of public funding for basic services together
with topup private funding.
2
The focus of our analysis is on the second and third rationale for dual practice. We consider
the provision of a basic treatment to which patients have access at no cost within a public health
plan, while, within dual practice, a more effective but more costly treatment may be offered at
an outofpocket fee. Even though the more intensive treatment is not costeffective for the
1
GarciaPrado and Gonzalez (2011) provide an excellent summary on both the prevalence of dual practice within
developed and developing countries and on its benefits and disadvantages. See Ferrinho, van Lerberghe, Fronteira,
Hipólito, and Biscaia (2004), GarciaPrado and Gonzalez (2007), and Socha and Bech (2011) for additional surveys on
the theme.
2
Barros and Siciliani (2011) and Hurley and Johnson (2014) offer excellent surveys on the economics of publicprivate
health care financing.
KUHN AND NUSCHELER
|
1121

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT