Rules of evidence and liability in contract litigation: The efficiency of the General Dynamics rule

AuthorSimon J. Wilkie,Vlad Radoias,Michael A. Williams
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12279
Published date01 December 2017
Date01 December 2017
Received: 7 August 2017 Accepted: 8 October 2017
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12279
ARTICLE
Rules of evidence and liability in contract litigation:
The efficiency of the General Dynamics rule
Vlad Radoias1Simon J. Wilkie2Michael A. Williams3
1SamHouston State University
2Universityof Southern California and Microsoft
3CompetitionEconomics LLC
VladRadoias, Department of Economics and
InternationalBusiness, Sam Houston State Uni-
versity,Box 2118, Huntsville, TX 77341, USA
(radoias@shsu.edu).
SimonJ. Wilkie, Department of Economics, Uni-
versityof Southern California, 3620 South Ver-
montAvenue, KAP300, Los Angeles, CA 90089,
USA(swilkie@usc.edu).
MichaelA. Williams, Competition Economics LLC,
2000Powell Street, Suite 510, Emeryville, CA
94608,USA (mwilliams@c-econ.com).
Wethank Brijesh Pinto, three anonymous ref-
erees,and the editors for helpful comments. We
alsothank William Havens, David Park, and Lara
Yangfor research assistance.
We examine rules of evidence and liability in contract litigation.
When a contractor fails to perform, it has a legal defense that the
buyer withheld private information relevant to the performance of
the contract. Suppose the buyer claims that admitting evidence for
thedefense would compromise a valuable secret, for example, a state
secret, what should the legal rule be? We show that the evidentiary
rules introduced by the Supreme Court in General Dynamics v. U.S.
leadto a more efficient outcome than either a strict liability rule or an
evidentiary rule requiring the disclosure of the buyer's private infor-
mation.
1INTRODUCTION
In 1988, the U.S.Navy awarded through a procurement auction a $4.8 billion fixed-price contract to General Dynamics
Corporation and McDonnell Douglas Corporation for the design and production of an advanced, carrier-based stealth
aircraft called the A-12 Avenger.The government agreed to share certain classified information with the contractors
because the project relied on state-of-the-art stealth technology already being used in other government programs,
and such technology would have been prohibitively costly and time-consuming to reproduce (Schwinn, 2011). The
project soon encountered a series of delays, and after failing to meet various benchmarks, the contractors formally
requested a restructuring of the contract from a fixed-priceto a cost-reimbursement agreement, arguing that the cost
was much higher than originally anticipated. Failing to reach an agreement and dissatisfied with the lack of progress,
the Navy terminated the contract for default in 1991 and sought repaymentof $1.3 billion plus $2.5 billion in accumu-
lated interest.
The contractors countersued the United States claiming that their inability to complete the project was excusable
due to the government's failure to share its superior knowledge regarding stealth technology. As a general principle
in contract law, either the impossibility to perform or the withholding of keyprivate information by the principal is an
admissible legal defense (Posner, 2005; Posner & Rosenfield, 1977). In response, the government invoked the state-
secrets privilege to prevent the classified information from being used as evidence. Thus, the contractorswere caught
Journal of Public Economic Theory.2017;19:1154–1165. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet c
2017 Wiley Periodicals,Inc. 1154

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT