Robert bork and vertical integration: leverage, foreclosure, and efficiency

AuthorHerbert Hovenkamp
PositionBen V. & Dorothy Willie Professor of Law and History, University of Iowa
Pages983-1001
ROBERT BORK AND VERTICAL INTEGRATION:
LEVERAGE, FORECLOSURE, AND EFFICIENCY
H
ERBERT
H
OVENKAMP
*
Vertical integration occurs when a firm produces or uses something inter-
nally that it might otherwise purchase from or sell to others. For example, an
automobile manufacturer that produces its own engines is vertically integrated
“upstream” into a source of supply. If it also owns some of its retail sales
stores, it is said to be vertically integrated “downstream” into distribution.
Robert H. Bork wrote extensively about vertical integration, and defended
it as nearly always procompetitive. When Bork began to write about vertical
integration in the 1950s, the courts feared that a vertically integrated parent
company might “force” its subsidiary to deal with the parent. Bork noted that
this analysis improperly assumed a market limited to the subsidiary.
1
The al-
ternative theory of vertical integration that Bork presented a quarter century
later in his seminal book, The Antitrust Paradox, was beguilingly simple: If
vertical integration creates efficiencies, then a vertically integrated firm would
have cost advantages over unintegrated rivals. This might deter entry, but only
as a result of increased competition. And, if vertical integration did not create
any efficiencies, then it would not impede entry. Either way, vertical integra-
tion would not harm the competitive process. Bork drew similar conclusions
about all forms of vertical integration, including vertical mergers and vertical
integration by contract—mainly exclusive dealing, resale price maintenance,
and tying.
* Ben V. & Dorothy Willie Professor of Law and History, University of Iowa. Thanks to
Professor Kenneth G. Elzinga for commenting on a draft.
1
Robert H. Bork, Vertical Integration and the Sherman Act: The Legal History of an Eco-
nomic Misconception, 22 U. C
HI
. L. R
EV
. 157, 186 (1954) [hereinafter Bork, Vertical Integra-
tion] (referring to United States v. Lehigh Valley R. Co., 254 U.S. 255 (1920)).
983
984
A
NTITRUST
L
AW
J
OURNAL
[Vol. 79
I. BORK AND THE HISTORICAL TREATMENT OF
VERTICAL INTEGRATION
One might imagine a close relationship between the rise of large integrated
firms in the United States and the growth of legal hostility toward vertical
integration. The development of vertically integrated firms occurred much
earlier, however, and generally in a policy regime that was relatively benign.
Standard Oil, Ford Motor Company, United States Steel, International Har-
vester, and other vertically integrated firms all developed prior to the 1920s. A
1911 antitrust decree broke up Standard Oil but said little about Standard’s
vertical integration.
2
For two decades following that decision, the lower courts
were favorably inclined toward vertical integration in the petroleum industry.
3
In 1920, the Supreme Court refused to condemn a vertical merger involving
United States Steel.
4
International Harvester, which became the largest pro-
ducer of agricultural implements in the early 20th century, initially acquired
and operated its own coal mines, steel mills, railroads, and forest land for
producing lumber.
5
Bork began writing about vertical integration and antitrust policy upon
graduating from law school at the University of Chicago in 1953. His first
article on the subject, Vertical Integration and the Sherman Act, published a
year later, noted a recent increase in antitrust attacks on vertical integration,
but argued that these attacks had been happening since the early 1900s.
6
At
the time Bork was writing, there was plenty of judicial hostility toward verti-
cal integration. But Bork considerably overstated his case about the period
prior to the 1930s. He found a few early decisions that condemned vertical
integration as predatory or monopolistic when the defendant was a dominant
firm, and extrapolated from those.
7
For example, United States v. Corn Prod-
ucts Refining Co. introduced the “price squeeze” theory of harm. The court
2
Standard Oil Co. of N.J. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1, 76–77 (1911). See George Ellery
Hale, Trust Dissolution: “Atomizing” Business Units of a Monopolistic Size, 40 C
OLUM
. L. R
EV
.
615, 624 (1940).
3
See, e.g., United States v. Standard Oil Co. of N.J., 47 F.2d 288, 299, 309–11 (E.D. Mo.
1931).
4
United States v. U.S. Steel Corp., 251 U.S. 417, 442 (1920). Henry Ford managed to escape
antitrust liability, notwithstanding vertical integration to seemingly paranoid levels. He even
grew his own soybeans for the production of plastic horn buttons for the Model T. G.E. Hale,
Vertical Integration: Impact of the Antitrust Laws upon Combinations of Successive Stages of
Production and Distribution, 49 C
OLUM
. L. R
EV
. 921, 922 (1949).
5
See F
ED
. T
RADE
C
OMM
N
, C
AUSES OF THE
H
IGH
P
RICES OF
F
ARM
I
MPLEMENTS
672–75
(1920); see generally International Harvester, F
ORTUNE
, Aug. 1933, at 21.
6
Bork, Vertical Integration,supra note 1, at 157 n.2 (1954) (citing Hale, supra note 4, at
923; Comment, Vertical Forestalling Under the Antitrust Laws, 19 U. C
HI
. L. R
EV
. 583, 584
(1952); Alfred E. Kahn, A Legal and Economic Appraisal of the “New” Sherman and Clayton
Acts, 63 Y
ALE
L.J. 293, 341 (1954)).
7
United States v. Am. Tobacco Co., 221 U.S. 106 (1911); United States v. Corn Prods. Ref.
Co., 234 F. 964 (S.D.N.Y. 1916), appeal dismissed, 249 U.S. 621 (1919); United States v. East-

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT