RISK‐SHIFTING BEHAVIOR AT COMMERCIAL BANKS WITH DIFFERENT DEPOSIT INSURANCE ASSESSMENTS: FURTHER EVIDENCE FROM U.S. MARKETS

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jfir.12117
Published date01 March 2017
AuthorChuang‐Chang Chang,Ruey‐Jenn Ho
Date01 March 2017
RISK-SHIFTING BEHAVIOR AT COMMERCIAL BANKS WITH DIFFERENT
DEPOSIT INSURANCE ASSESSMENTS: FURTHER EVIDENCE FROM
U.S. MARKETS
Chuang-Chang Chang
National Central University
Ruey-Jenn Ho
Providence University
Abstract
In this article, we investigate both the risk-shifting behavior of banks and the extent to
which risk was controlled after the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation adopted a
risk-based assessment system in U.S. markets. The risk-shifting behavior of commercial
banks was signicantly mitigated by the adoption of a risk-based deposit insurance
assessment system. The risk-shifting incentive remains, especially for less capitalized or
higher premium banks, which suggests that during 19922008, risk-based assessments
reduced but did not eliminate the moral hazard problem in banks. Moreover, the results
reveal that larger banks did not risk shift more than did smaller banks following the 1991
deposit insurance reform.
JEL Classification: G21, G28
I. Introduction
In the nance literature, the role of deposit insurance is a debatable issue. In general,
deposit insurance aims to protect depositors and prevent them from making unnecessary
withdrawals. Diamond and Dybvig (1983) show that deposit insurance protects nancial
institutions from instability and enhances the stability of a nancial system. However,
deposit insurance also provides nancial institutions with incentives to increase risks
and, if deposit insurance premiums do not reect those risks, to appropriately to shift
such risks to insurers.
When deposit insurance was introduced in the United States, the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation (FDIC) designed a xed-rate system. Under such a at-rate
assessment, most conjectures in the prior literature suggest that banks have incentives to
extract wealth from insurers (e.g., Mussa 1986; Kane 1987). Several studies show that
because the premiums within at-rate deposit insurance assessments are not risk
adjusted, the systems encourage banks to take excessive risks (e.g., Merton 1977;
We are grateful to the editors, Richard Brown (associate editor), and an anonymous referee for their
constructive suggestions and comments. We also thank Professors Jing-Twen Chen, Keng-Yu Ho, Sharon Yang,
Jeffrey Wang, and the participates of 2011 KFA&TFA joint conference for providing many valuable suggestions
on the prior version. All errors or omissions within are solely those of the authors.
The Journal of Financial Research Vol. XL, No. 1 Pages 5580 Spring 2017
55
© 2017 The Southern Finance Association and the Southwestern Finance Association
RAWLS COLLEGE OF BUSINESS, TEXAS TECH UNIVERSITY
PUBLISHED FOR THE SOUTHERN AND SOUTHWESTERN
FINANCE ASSOCIATIONS BY WILEY-BLACKWELL PUBLISHING
Pesando 1985). Therefore, a wealth transfer and moral hazard occurs when banks
intentionally increase their risk in at-rate deposit insurance conditions. To ameliorate
this incentive to take risks, the U.S. Congress introduced the Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation Improvement Act (FDICIA) of 1991; the FDIC implemented the risk-based
premium system in 1992. Since then, federal regulators have been able to monitor banks
in a risk-based assessment system. To the extent that deposit insurance premiums are not
correctly priced, though, it has not been clear whether the moral hazard is mitigated.
1
Existing empirical evidence on ri sk shifting at commercial banks is mi xed.
Several studies of this iss ue in the U.S. market have show n that insured banks took
excessive risks and shifted the ir risk to the FDIC. For example, Grossman (1992) nds
a positive relation between depos it insurance and bank risk taking in the U.S. ma rket.
Hovakimian and Kane (2000) nd tha t the deposit insurance system did not
prevent U.S. banks from shift ing their risk onto the FDIC , especially in cases of banks
that were undercapitalized and had a higher deposit-to-debt ratio. Ev idence from other
countries also identies poten tial risk-shifting problem s among banks. Wagster (20 07)
conrms that the adoption of e xplicit deposit insurance ex panded risk-shifting
incentives for Canadian bank s and trust companies. Ioannido u and Penas (2010) nd
that Bolivia banks were more likely to initiate riskier loans during the post-deposit-
insurance period. Using an i nternational country sampl e, Demirg
uSc-Kun t and
Detragiache (2002) and Hova kimian, Kane, and Laeven (20 03) nd that deposit
insurance increased the risk-shifting probability, especially in countries with weak
nancial environments, low levels of political and economic freedom, and high levels
of corruption.
However, several studies also offer contrasting evidence regarding risk-shifting
behavior. Flannery (1989) argues that existing regulatory practices, linking capital
adequacy to loan quality, could eliminate risk shifting. Duan, Moreau, and Sealey (1992)
suggest that risk shifting is not widespread in the U.S. market, with some exceptions.
Karels and McClatchey (1999) nd that the adoption of deposit insurance in the 1970s
decreased the risk taking of U.S. credit unions.
In light of these conicting results, it seems warranted to seek further evidence
regarding the effect of deposit insurance on the risk-shifting behavior of banks. In
particular, we compare the risk-shifting behavior of banks before and after the
introduction of the risk-based premium system in the U.S. market. We focus our tests on
deposit insurance reform for two reasons. First, study samples have covered the period of
deposit insurance reform, which contains a clear structured break and therefore may
cause a structured change in banksrisk-shifting behavior. Second, most empirical
results from previous studies focus on the risk-shifting behavior of banks during the
xed-rate deposit insurance period in the U.S. market. We are more interested in
investigating risk-shifting behavior during the period of risk-based deposit insurance and
1
For example, in the early 2000s, the designated reserve ratio restricted the FDIC from charging premiums to
well-capitalized and highly rated banks as long as the insurance fund reserves were above 1.25% of insured
deposits. As a result, more than 90% of all insured banks did not pay deposit insurance premiums in the early 2000s,
and therefore, the system did not effectively price risk.
56 The Journal of Financial Research

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT