RISK MISPERCEPTIONS AND SELECTION IN INSURANCE MARKETS: AN APPLICATION TO DEMAND FOR CANCER INSURANCE

Published date01 September 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jori.12180
Date01 September 2018
AuthorDavid Hales,Mary Riddel
RISK MISPERCEPTIONS AND SELECTION IN INSURANCE
MARKETS:ANAPPLICATION TO DEMAND FOR CANCER
INSURANCE
Mary Riddel
David Hales
ABSTRACT
We test for the influence of optimism on selection in a hypothetical cancer-
insurance market using a survey of 474 subjects. We elicit perceptions of
baseline cancer risk and control efficacy and combine these with subject-
specific cancer risks predicted by the Harvard Cancer Risk Index to develop
measures of baseline and control optimism. Following Fang, Keane, and
Silverman (2008), we hypothesize that a variable may lead to advantageous
selection if it is positively correlated with both prevention effort and demand
for insurance. We find evidence of selection from both baseline and control
optimism, but little evidence of selection from cognitive ability and risk
aversion. We then estimate a model that allows us to classify subjects
according to their excess risk-reducing effort and excess insurance uptake
that occurs solely because of baseline and control optimism. We find subjects
who overinsure relative to a subject with accurate risk beliefs are likely to
have lower expected treatment costs, ceteris paribus. This indicates that on
net, baseline and control optimism leads to advantageous selection in our
sample.
Economists have long posited that asymmetric information with heterogeneous risk
types can lead to adverse selection in insurance markets (Rothschild and Stiglitz,
1976). Individuals with private information that they are high-risk types tend to buy
more coverage than low-risk types. High-risk types will also have higher claims,
leading to a positive correlation between insurance coverage and claims. Such
positive correlations have been found in some markets but rejected in others. For
example, Puelz and Snow (1994) find evidence of adverse selection in the market for
Mary Riddel is Professor of Economics at the Department of Economics, Lee Business School,
4505 S. Maryland PKWY, Box 6005, University of Nevada, Las Vegas, NV 89154-6005. Riddel
can be contacted via e-mail: mriddel@unlv.nevada.edu. David Hales is a graduate student at
the Department of Economics, University of California, Santa Barbara. The authors would like
to acknowledge helpful comments from Paul Thistle; the Harvard Risk, Perception, and
Response Conference held in March 2014; the CEAR/MRIC Behavioral Insurance Workshop in
Munich held in December 2014; and two anonymous referees.
© 2016 The Journal of Risk and Insurance. Vol. 85, No. 3, 749–785 (2018).
DOI: 10.1111/jori.12180
749
automobile insurance, but Chiappori and Salanie (2000) do not. Finkelstein and
McGarry (2006) reject the hypothesis of adverse selection in their study of long-term
care insurance.
These mixed findings concerning adverse selection have led researchers to look for
other sources of private information and selection in insurance markets. De Meza and
Webb (2001) develop a model where risk aversion leads to advantageous selection as
more risk-averse subjects buy more insurance and simultaneously engage in more
prevention behavior, leading to a negative correlation between coverage and claims.
Fang, Keane, and Silverman (2008) examine the market for Medigap insurance
(a supplement to Medicare). Controlling for cognitive ability, they find a negative
correlation between coverage and ex post claims that is indicative of advantageous
selection. They conclude that the correlation arises because cognitive ability is
correlated with both good health and the purchase of health insurance.
A recent article by Spinnewijn (2013) posits that heterogeneity in risk misperceptions
may also affect the relationships between coverage and claims. Spinnewijn recognizes
two dimensions of risk misperception. First, subjects may be relatively “baseline
optimistic,” meaning they believe their risk of damages is lower than it actually is.
Baseline optimistic subjects demand less insurance than their more pessimistic
counterparts. “Control optimists” overestimate the risk reductions from engaging in
preventative activities and avoiding risky activities. As a result, they overinvest in
risk-reducing activities relative to their true risk type, leading to lower expected
insurance claims. Assuming a simple model with two insurees with different
perceived risk types and incentive-compatible equilibrium contracts, Spinnewijn
shows that if one insuree is both more baseline optimistic and more control optimistic
than the other, a positive correlation between coverage and claims will occur. A
negative correlation results if instead the more control pessimistic type is also
relatively more baseline optimistic. Thus, depending on the net effect of control and
baseline optimism, either adverse or advantageous selection may result.
Ideally, we could test for selection arising from baseline and control optimism and
other possible selection variablesusing the Fang, Keane, and Silverman (2008) test for
multidimensional selection.They maintain that for a variable to lead to advantageous
selection it must have two properties: (1) the variable is positively correlated with
coverage and (2) the variable is negatively correlated with insurance claims.
Unfortunately, we are not aware of a database that includes subject-level coverage
and claims data as well as measures of controland baseline optimism related to cancer
risk and insurance. As such, we take a novel approach to investigating selection in
insurance markets. Rather than analyzing historical insurance coverage and claims
data, we examinethe relationship between prevention effort (a proxyfor ex post claims)
and willingness to pay for an insurance contract that covers all of the costs of cancer
treatment (a proxy for demand for insurance coverage). Prevention effort is a
reasonable proxyfor expected claims as increased prevention effort strongly correlates
with lower expected claims. Demand for insurance is increasing in willingness to pay
for a fixed contract, making willingness to pay a good proxy for coverage.
Using an online survey of 474 U.S. adults aged 18 and older, we test for
multidimensional selection in a hypothetical cancer insurance market arising from
750 THE JOURNAL OF RISK AND INSURANCE
baseline and control optimism, risk aversion, and cognitive ability while controlling
for observable demographic variables. We first elicit measures of baseline risk
perceptions and perceptions of the efficacy of prevention efforts for colon, prostate,
and bladder cancer in men, and colon, breast, and bladder cancers in women. We
query subjects about their behaviors that may either reduce or increase risks for
these cancers, allowing us to devise a measure of prevention effort. We elicit estimates
of the subject’s degree of risk aversion using Holt and Laury’s (2002) multiple
price-list elicitation method. We measure cognitive ability using a short intelligence
assessment.
1
Finally, we ask subjects if they would be willing to pay some stated
premium Pfor insurance that would cover all their cancer costs. This final question
allows us to develop a measure of willingness to pay for insurance as a function of the
selection and demographic variables.
To our knowledge, no other research has empirically evaluated the role of control and
baseline optimism in selection in insurance markets. This is likely because data on
actual and perceived risk as well as actual and perceived prevention efficacy that are
needed to create optimism variables are generally not available. Thus, the strength of
this study is that our measures of cancer risk misperception rest on combining
subjects’ survey responses with the Harvard Cancer Risk Index (HCRI) (Colditz et al.,
2000) to form measures of baseline and control optimism. The HCRI was developed at
the Harvard Center for Cancer Prevention by a working group of “epidemiologists,
clinical oncologists, and other Harvard faculty with quantitative expertise focused on
cancer and risk assessment” (Colditz et al., 2000). The HCRI provides quantitative
relative risk (RR) factors for each demographic or behavioral attribute that experts
believe bear on the risk of incidence of a given cancer. The HCRI can thus be used to
calculate the risk a subject will contract cancer, conditional on their behavioral and
demographic traits. We derive a measure of baseline optimism by asking subjects to
estimate their risk of incidence of each cancer and comparing this with corresponding
HCRI estimates. Similarly, we derive a measure of control optimism by asking
subjects how effective a series of preventative measures are in reducing cancer risk,
and how risky a series of unhealthy behaviors are, and then comparing their response
with corresponding HCRI RR factors.
Like Fang, Keane, and Silverman (2008), we hypothesize that variables that are
positively correlated with willingness to pay for insurance and prevention effort lead
to advantageous selection in the insurance market. Adverse selection results if a
variable is positively correlated with willingness to pay and negatively correlated
with effort. We first estimate models of the willingness to pay for insurance as a
function of baseline optimism, controlling for observable demographic variables. We
1
Recent articles find that a large proportion of experimental subjects have risk preference
functions that are best described by cumulative prospect theory where probability weighting
and loss aversion together with standard utility function-based risk aversion define
preferences (Conte, Hey, and Moffatt 2011; Barseghyan et al., 2013). In the current article,
we explicitly account for utility-based risk aversion. Some argue that optimism is a form of
probability weighting (e.g., Quiggin, 1993) and thus we also explicitly account for probability-
based risk aversion. Since the risks in the current article are defined solely over losses,
accounting for loss aversion is not necessary.
RISK MISPERCEPTION AND SELECTION 751

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT