Revisiting the investment anomaly: Financing constraints or limits‐to‐arbitrage?

Published date01 October 2020
AuthorKyungyeon (Rachel) Koh
Date01 October 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/rfe.1098
Rev Financ Econ. 2020;38:655–673. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/rfe
|
655
© 2020 University of New Orleans
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Firm investments have negatively predicted future stock returns in cross sections after controlling for the standard risks. There
are two prominent hypotheses for this pervasive return predictability: (a) prolonged mispricing due to limits to arbitrage and (b)
financing constraints (FCs) affecting the link between the corporate investment process and the discount rate.
The mispricing hypothesis suggests that certain behavioral biases, such as over- or under-reaction to information, lead to
stock overvaluation following large investments undertaken by firms. Although arbitrageurs in an efficient market should
promptly correct the mispricing, limits to arbitrage due to capital shortage, excessive transaction costs and/or information
risk may discourage the arbitrageurs from fully acting on the overvaluation (Shleifer & Vishny, 1997). For instance, previous
studies have attributed the persistence of the momentum and post-earnings drift anomalies long after their discovery to such
risks borne by the arbitrageurs (Mendenhall, 2004; Sadka, 2006). The arguments for the effect of limits to arbitrage on the
investment-related anomalies are mixed. Some studies document the evidence that the anomalies exist due to high barriers to
arbitrage (Lakonishok, Shleifer, & Vishny, 1994; Li & Sullivan, 2011); others associate the anomalies with the systematic risk
related to the firm's growth options (Li, Livdan, & Zhang, 2009; Zhang, 2006). If the return predictability of firm investments
is statistically and economically stronger in firms with higher arbitrage costs, then the expected return-investment relation is
likely attributable to the limits to arbitrage.
Alternatively, a non-behavioral explanation for the return predictability can bring insights from the Q-theory of investment
(Cochrane, 1991, 1996) extended with the inclusion of FCs by Li and Zhang (2010). In imperfect markets with informational
asymmetry, agency costs and transaction costs, internal and external financing are not perfect substitutes, and smoothing in-
vestments becomes more challenging for firms (Fazzari, Hubbard, Petersen, Blinder, & Poterba, 1988; Kaplan & Zingales,
1997). Then, the investment anomaly may likely be the byproduct of a firm's investment optimization process: firms increasing
Received: 8 July 2019
|
Revised: 16 December 2019
|
Accepted: 17 December 2019
DOI: 10.1002/rfe.1098
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Revisiting the investment anomaly: Financing constraints or
limits-to-arbitrage?
Kyungyeon (Rachel)Koh
Department of Finance, California State
University—Channel Islands, Thousand
Oaks, CA, USA
Correspondence
Kyungyeon (Rachel) Koh, Department
of Finance, California State University—
Channel Islands, Thousand Oaks, CA, USA.
Email: rachel.koh@csuci.edu
Abstract
The investment anomaly refers to the pervasive negative predictability in future stock
returns following large firm investments. I re-investigate two competing hypotheses
for the potential source of the anomaly: (a) prolonged mispricing due to limits to
arbitrage and (b) financing constraints in the context of Q-theory of investments.
The analyses employ new proxies for financing constraints, the text-based measures
developed by Hoberg and Maksimovic (2014). While the evidence supporting the
limits-to-arbitrage hypothesis is stronger, there is a fair amount of evidence that fi-
nancing constraints also reinforce the anomaly effect.
KEYWORDS
financing constraints, investment anomaly, limits to arbitrage, mispricing
JEL CLASSIFICATION
G12; G31
656
|
KOH
investments must have low discount rates, especially if they face high FCs. I empirically test this theoretical outcome by using
proxies for FCs and examining whether the return predictability is stronger in more financially constrained firms.
The results contribute to the current state of research on the source of the investment anomaly, which remains inconclusive
to date. To preserve comparability with the previous two articles that have compared the two hypotheses, Li and Zhang (2010)
and Lam and Wei (2011), I use the same rigorous statistical and econometric methods. However, this research updates the
sample up to the year 2018, while previous studies examine up to 2009, which is meaningful because some market anomalies,
including the investment anomalies examined in this study, have weakened over time (Chordia, Subrahmanyam, & Tong, 2014).
In addition, this study tests the hypotheses with new and advanced FC variables, which no previous research has undertaken.
Specifically, the tests employ the text-based FC metrics developed by Hoberg and Maksimovic (2014); these new measures
have been shown to capture the degree of financing costs with less noise than the traditional measures based on firm charac-
teristics. It is important to re-investigate the hypotheses with the new development in the literature. In short, this research finds
stronger evidence that supports the limits to arbitrage as the source of the investment anomaly, but interestingly, there is a fair
amount of evidence that FCs also reinforce the anomaly effect.
2
|
HYPOTHESIS DEVELOPMENT
The return predictability due to mispricing can persist over a longer period if arbitrageurs are discouraged from acting on the
mispricing immediately due to high arbitrage costs (Shleifer & Vishny, 1997). Hence, we expect that the persistence of the
overpriced-ness following large firm investments will be greater in stocks with higher arbitrage costs. To test this concept em-
pirically, I employ idiosyncratic volatility (IVOL) of stock returns, a conventional measure for arbitrage costs (Ang, Hodrick,
Xing, & Zhang, 2006 and Stambaugh, Yu, & Yuan, 2015). The higher the idiosyncratic risk, the more difficult and expensive
the riskless arbitrage effort is.1
We expect to find a stronger inverse expected return-investment relation in the high IVOL firms
than in the low IVOL firms.
Another channel through which the inverse relation between the expected return and firm investments is the discount rate. In
the framework of the production-based asset pricing model by Cochrane (1991), corporate investment decisions reflect changes
in expected discount rates in the economy. All else equal, firms will invest more (less) when the cost of capital is lower (higher),
which potentially provides an explanation for the investment anomaly. In the extended version by Li and Zhang (2010), in-
vestment decisions are also influenced by the varying levels of FCs faced by firms. All else equal, firms with higher (lower)
constraints will have lower (higher) flexibility to adjust the level of investment in accordance with the cost of external capital.
The setup of the Q-theory with investment frictions by Li and Zhang (2010) is as follows. Each firm indexed by i chooses
the optimal investment level,
I
i0
to maximize the market value of the firm at the beginning of the period, t=0. Each firm faces
a gross discount rate Ri that are different across firms and also some degree of FCs
𝜆i
, that are also different across firms. A
firm's operating profit,
, is assumed to be time-invariant and constant across firms. Each firm will maximize its market value
by varying
Ii0
at the beginning of each period t=0, and the following equation is the first-order condition of the optimization
problem with respect to
Ii0
arranged for
Ri
:
Assuming all else constant, the inverse relation between
Ri
and
I
i0Ki0
serves as a potential explanation for the investment
anomaly. The intensity of that relation depends on the degree of FCs,
𝜆i
. Figure 1 shows how
Ri
varies with
I
i0Ki0
for different
levels of
𝜆i
, holding
constant at 0.15 and
𝛿
at 0 (rate of capital depreciation). Letting
vary from −0.02 to 1 and
𝜆i
from
0 to 30, we obtain a steeper relation at higher levels of
𝜆i
.
The pattern in the plot suggests that firms increasing investments must have low discount rates, especially if they face high
FCs.
The limits-to-arbitrage and FC explanations motivate the following set of hypotheses:
Hypothesis 1a If mispricing is the source of the return predictability, then the investment anomaly will appear stronger in
higher limits-to-arbitrage firms than in lower limits-to-arbitrage firms.
Hypothesis 1b If the Q-theory is the source of the return predictability, then the investment anomaly will appear stronger in
more financially constrained firms than in less financially constrained firms.
Ri=
+1𝛿
1+𝜆
i
(I
i0
K
i0)

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT