Return predictability of variance differences: A fractionally cointegrated approach

Date01 July 2020
AuthorXingzhi Yao,Marwan Izzeldin,Zhenxiong Li
Published date01 July 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/fut.22110
J Futures Markets. 2020;40:10721089.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/fut1072
|
© 2020 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Received: 24 April 2019
|
Accepted: 17 February 2020
DOI: 10.1002/fut.22110
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Return predictability of variance differences:
A fractionally cointegrated approach
Zhenxiong Li
1
|Marwan Izzeldin
2
|Xingzhi Yao
3
1
Department of Economics, Dongwu
Business School, Soochow University,
Suzhou, China
2
Department of Economics, Lancaster
University, Lancaster, UK
3
Finance Department, International Business
School Suzhou (IBSS), Xi'an Jiaotong
Liverpool University, Suzhou, China
Correspondence
Xingzhi Yao, International Business School
Suzhou (IBSS), Xi'an JiaotongLiverpool
University, 215123 Suzhou, China.
Email: Xingzhi.Yao@xjtlu.edu.cn
Funding information
Xi'an JiaotongLiverpool University,
China, Grant/Award Number:
RDF170207
Abstract
This paper examines the fractional cointegration between downside (upside)
components of realized and implied variances. A positive association is found
between the strength of their cofractional relation and the return predictability
of their differences. That association is established via the common long
memory component of the variances that are fractionally cointegrated, which
represents the volatilityofvolatility factor that determines the variance
premium. Our results indicate that market fears play a critical role not only in
driving the longrun equilibrium relationship between impliedrealized
variances but also in understanding the return predictability. A simulation
study further verifies these claims.
KEYWORDS
fractional cointegration, return predictability, variance risk premium
JEL CLASSIFICATION
C14; C32; C51
1|INTRODUCTION
Numerous empirical studies suggest that, unlike the variance, the variance risk premium (
V
R
P
) carries nontrivial
predictive power for aggregate stock market returns over quarterly to annual horizons, where the degree of return
predictability is greater than that afforded by more conventional predictors, see, Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009),
Drechsler and Yaron (2010), Bollerslev, Marrone, Xu, and Zhou (2014), and Bali and Zhou (2016), among others. Those
studies also provide strong evidence that much of the predictability implicit in the
V
R
P
may be attributed to its close
relation with macroeconomic uncertainty and aggregate risk aversion.
The
V
R
P
is formally defined as the wedge between optionimplied and realized variances. It is measured as the
difference between (the square of) the CBOE VIX index and the statistical expectation of the future return variation. In
Bollerslev et al. (2009), Drechsler and Yaron (2010) and Bollerslev, Sizova, and Tauchen (2012), the return predictability
of the
V
R
P
is investigated using a selfcontained general equilibrium model. This is in the spirit of the longrun risks
(LRR) model pioneered by Bansal and Yaron (2004). Specifically, Bollerslev et al. (2009) and Bollerslev et al. (2012)
extend the LRR model by allowing the timevarying volatilityofvolatility (volofvol) within the economy to be gen-
erated by its own stochastic process. They further show that the difference between the riskneutral and the objective
expectations of return variation isolates the volofvol factor, which then serves as the sole source of the true
V
R
P
. The
V
R
P
, therefore, displays good predictive power for future returns in cases where the volofvol plays a more dominant
role in determining variation in the equity premium. A direct link between the
V
R
P
and the volofvol is also de-
monstrated in a purely probabilistic model introduced by BarndorffNielsen and Veraart (2013).
By incorporating jumps in the LRR model, Drechsler and Yaron (2010) disentangle the difference in the drifts of
conditional variance from the
V
R
P
. That drift difference is related to the volofvol associated with the level of
uncertainty, leading to the covariation between the
V
R
P
and the conditional equity premium that is partially dependent
on the volofvol factor. As indicated by Bollerslev et al. (2009), the volofvol is inherently latent and may be variously
defined across different volatility models. Recent literature has achieved limited progress in seeking an appropriate
proxy of the volofvol factor which is necessary to explain the return predictability suggested by the
V
R
P
. A notable
exception is the work of Conrad and Loch (2015), where the volofvol is represented by the longterm volatility
component of the GARCHMIDAS model.
Consistent with the generalized LRR model discussed above, results suggested by Bollerslev, Osterrieder, Sizova,
and Tauchen (2013) provide new evidence for return predictability of the
V
R
P
based on the idea of fractional coin-
tegration. Given the mounting empirical studies that favor fractional integration in implied and realized variances (see
Bandi and Perron (2006) and Nielsen (2007) for instance), fast mean reversion in the
V
R
P
, that is the difference between
the two variances, points to the existence of fractional cointegration. Compared to the use of the univariate variances as
a proxy for risk, Bollerslev et al. (2013) show that the less persistent
V
R
P
rebalances the riskreturn regression in terms
of the order of fractional integration, and that this appears to be more informative for future returns. In addition, the
V
R
P
is estimated as the cointegrating relation between the two variances, which is highly linked to the volofvol and
aggregate economic uncertainty.
Another strand of the literature on the properties of the
V
R
P
focuses on the decomposition of the
V
R
P
into its
downside and upside components, so differentiating between investors' attitudes toward uncertainty risks associated
with the left and right tail of the return distribution. Feunou, JahanParvar, and Okou (2017) find that the downside
V
R
P
often dominates total
V
R
P
in predicting future excess returns. They rationalize this result by showing (a) that the
two components exhibit opposite relationships to the equity premium and (b) that the link between the upside
V
R
P
and
the equity premium is insignificant. In similar vein, Kilic and Shaliastovich (2018) adopt an alternative decomposition
of the
V
R
P
: they argue that both good and bad components contain important information about future excess returns,
which results in higher return predictability than that inherent in the total
V
R
P
.
The difference between the components of the realized (implied) variance is also considered in several studies
where the main focus is on equity risk premium predictability. For instance, by decomposing the realized jump
volatility into negative jumps and positive jumps, Guo, Wang, and Zhou (2019) construct the signed jump (SJ) risk as
the difference between the two jump risk components. In addition, the SJ risk is found to contain information about
future market returns that is independent of that captured by the
V
R
P
. With an alternative decomposition approach,
Bollerslev, Li, and Zhao (2019) derive the SJ variation as the difference between the good and bad realized volatility and
show that this difference significantly predicts the variation in future returns. Under the riskneutral measure, Huang
and Li (2019) identify a significant relationship between future stock returns and implied variance asymmetry (IVA)
defined as the difference between the upside and downside semivariances derived from outofthemoney (OTM)
options.
Against this backdrop, the main contributions of this paper are threefold. First, by decomposing the implied and
realized variances into upside and downside components, we investigate the presence of fractional cointegration in
each pair of semivariances and establish new evidence for the longrun relationship between different variance
components. Second, we show that the common longmemory component in the fractionally cointegrated system, as
part of the conditional variance of market returns, is intimately associated with the volofvol driving the variance
premium. Moreover, that common component plays a key role in connecting the strength of the fractional cointegration
between variances and the stock return predictability afforded by the variance differences. The dominant predictive
power of the downside
V
R
P
documented in the literature can therefore, be reasonably explained by the longrun
equilibrium relation between the downside implied and realized semivariances. Third, to alleviate the impact on our
empirical findings of the limited availability of observed strikes in the construction of implied variances, we employ a
simulation study to verify the claims outlined above.
Following the procedures of BarndorffNielsen, Kinnebrock, and Shephard (2010) and Andersen, Bondarenko, and
GonzalezPerez (2015), we obtain upside and downside semivariances of the realized (RV ) and implied (IV ) variances,
which we refer to as RV RV I V,,
UD
U
, and
IVD
. The difference between IV IV()
UD
and
RV RV(
)
UD
is defined as the
upside (downside) variance risk premium, henceforth
V
RP VRP(
)
UD
. The SJ and IVA are, respectively, measured as the
difference between
RV
U
and
RV
D
and the difference between
IV
U
and
IVD
. Using a semiparametric approach, we
demonstrate the existence of a fractionally cointegrating relation in each pair of the semivariances listed above. In
addition, our results reveal the role of
IVD
as a longrun upward biased forecast of future
RV
. This evidence is also
LI ET AL.
|
1073

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT