Reputation versus information: The delegation policy when the principal has reputational concerns

AuthorTsung‐Sheng Tsai,Yasunari Tamada
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12289
Published date01 June 2018
Date01 June 2018
Received: 8 August 2017 Accepted: 13 January 2018
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12289
ARTICLE
Reputation versus information: The delegation
policy when the principal has reputational
concerns
Yasunari Tamada1Tsung-Sheng Tsai2
1KeioUniversity
2NationalTaiwan University
YasunariTamada,Faculty of Economics, Keio
University,2-15-45 Mita, Minato-ku, Tokyo
108-8345,Japan (tamada@econ.keio.ac.jp).
Tsung-ShengTsai,Department of Eco-
nomics,National TaiwanUniversity, No.
1,Sec. 4, Roosevelt Road, Taipei106,
Taiwan(tstsai@ntu.edu.tw).
Wesincerely thank the Associate Editor and
tworeferees for their insightful comments and
helpfulsuggestions. The second author also
acknowledgesthe financial support provided by
theMinistry of Science and Technology,Taiwan
(NSC93-2415-H-001-033).
We analyze the delegation policy when the principal has reputa-
tional concerns. Both the principal and the agent can be either good
or biased; the good players prefer the correct decision, while the
biased ones prefer a high action even though it may be wrong. An
evaluator who forms the principal's reputation may or may not be
able to observe who makes the decision. When the evaluator can-
notobserve the allocation of authority, the principal shares the credit
and blame with the agent. Although delegation can improvethe qual-
ity of decision making because the agent has better information, it
mayalso hurt the good principal's reputation because the high action
may be taken by the biased agent while the blame will be shared
when it is wrong. Thus, the good principal has a tendency to keep
too much authority to maintain her reputation. By contrast, when
the evaluator can observe the allocation of authority, delegation
becomes a signaling device for the good type of principal to differ-
entiate herself from the biased one. This results in an excessiveallo-
cation of authority toward the agent.
“Princes should delegate to others the enactment of unpopular measures and keep in their own hands the means of winning
favors.” — Niccolò Machiavelli
1INTRODUCTION
The epigraph noted by Niccolò Machiavelli 500 years ago underlines a fundamental and important question faced by
every decision maker:when should the decision-making authority be delegated to others? In reality, the degree of del-
egation of authority has not been monolithic but has varied in different issues and areas. For example, Epstein and
O'Halloran (1999) demonstrate that the U.S. Congress delegates the least authority to the Executivein issues related
to budgets, rules, and ways and means, but delegates the most in the areas of agricultural and public works and armed
services. Graham, Harvey,and Puri (2015) find that CEOs delegate less when they are more knowledgeable but dele-
gate more decisions when they are overloaded or when they are distracted byrecent acquisitions. Researchers have
Journal of Public Economic Theory.2018;20:367–389. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet c
2018 Wiley Periodicals,Inc. 367
368 TAMADAAND TSAI
been providing some good reasons for the principal to delegate the authority to the agent. One important reason is
to take advantage of the agent's expertise. If the principal delegates the authority,the quality of information may be
better, so that it is more likely that the right decision can be made; however, the difference in their preferences may
also lead to a biased decision. The principal thus faces a trade-off between a loss of control and a loss of information in
determining her delegation policy.
Another popular reason for delegation that has been emphasized, particularly in the political science literature,
is blame avoidance. Politicians who seek reelection are often motivated by the desire to avoid blame for unpopular
actions that might impair their reputation or the chance to win in the election. Thus, politicians tend to adopt some
strategies to avoid blame, such as agenda limitation, scapegoating, or “passing the buck.” Accordingly, delegation is
the result of politicians'efforts to “shift the responsibility” (Fiorina, 1982). For example, Congress often passes pro-
tectionist trade legislation, in the hope that the President will veto it and bear the wrath of the affected industries.
Independent regulatory commissions are often delegated responsibility for missions with conflicts that benefit some
industries at the expense of others, such as mergers or rate-making.1On the other hand, politicians also often seek to
“claim credit” through their activities for popular actions (Fiorina, 1977). Such an incentive encourages the principals
to make the decisions on their own to protect their political benefits.2In other words, policymakers care about their
reputation and may choose the actions that help them avoidblame or claim credit rather than the correct ones.
So far,these two points of view in analyzing the delegation policy have been considered separately in the literature.
This paper incorporates both perspectives to determine the delegation policy by introducing a new factor into the
typical trade-off between information and control: the principal's reputational concerns. Consider the situation where
there are three players: a principal (she), an agent (he), and an outside evaluator (he).One can interpret the principal
as a politician or a CEO, the agent as a bureaucrat or a division manager,and the evaluator as the median voter or the
stakeholder.Both the principal and the agent can be either good or biased, which is private information to themselves.
The good type prefers to choose a correct policy, and the biased type prefers some specific policy with a high action.
For example,if a politician plans to build up a public good, the good type will prefer a suitable size which can meet the
voter's demand, while the biased type will always want to build the largest size, which may be considered a spendthrift's
behavior.The principal can either make the decision on her own or delegate it to the agent, who has better information
regarding the state of the world. The evaluator prefers a correct decision to a wrong one. He also forms the principal's
reputation after observing the decision that has been made. Importantly,the principal cares not only about the chosen
decision but also her reputation. The interesting feature of our analysis is that the principal can use her delegation
policy to manipulate her reputation.
The biased principal's favorite policy is the high action, and therefore, when reputational concerns are not too
strong, she prefers to keep the authority all the time because the low (although correct) action may be chosen by the
good agent under delegation. An interesting question follows: Towhat extent would the good principal delegate her
authority, given that the biased type always holds on to power? Besides facing the typical trade-offbetween control
and information, her reputational concerns also play an active role. Importantly,the formation of her reputation cru-
cially depends on whether the allocation of authority can be observed by the evaluator or not. When the evaluator
cannot observe the allocation of authority, the responsibility for the decision making is ambiguous and the blame or
credit will be shared between the principal and the agent. Therefore, if the authority is delegated, the good principal
facesa new trade-off between utilizing the agent's better information and maintaining her reputation. On the one hand,
as the agent is more likely to take the correct action and only errs in the high action, the quality of decision making is
better.However, it is also likely that the high action is taken by the biased agent, which is also preferred by the biased
principal. As the blame is shared, delegation that leads to the high (and incorrect) action can hurt the good principal's
reputation.
1SeeEpstein and O'Halloran (1999) and Weaver (1986) for the detailed discussions.
2Forexample, Epstein and O'Halloran (1999) state that Congress uses considerable resources to write detailed legislation about tax policy and leaves little
authorityto the executive branch. The advantages of controlling tax policy come from the possible benefits of grantingcorporations and interest groups special
taxbreaks in exchange for their support or contributions in elections.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT