Reproductive health, fairness, and optimal policies

Published date01 September 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12436
Date01 September 2020
J Public Econ Theory. 2020;22:12131244. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet © 2020 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
|
1213
Received: 10 June 2019
|
Accepted: 18 February 2020
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12436
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Reproductive health, fairness, and optimal
policies
Johanna Etner
1
|Natacha Raffin
1,2
|Thomas Seegmuller
3
1
EconomiX, Université Paris Nanterre,
CNRS, Nanterre, France
2
CREAM, Université Rouen Normandie,
Rouen, France
3
AixMarseille University, CNRS, EHESS,
Centrale Marseille, AMSE
Correspondence
Natacha Raffin, CREAM, Université Rouen
Normandie, Rouen 76000, France.
Email: natacha.raffin@univ-rouen.fr
Abstract
We consider an overlapping generations economy in
which agents differ through their ability to procreate.
Exante infertile households may incur health ex-
penditure to increase their chances of parenthood.
This health heterogeneity generates welfare inequal-
ities that deserve to be ruled out. We explore three
different criteria of social evaluation in the longrun:
the utilitarian approach, the exante egalitarian cri-
terion and the expost egalitarian one. We propose a
set of economic instruments to decentralize each
solution. To correct for the externalities and health
inequalities, both a preventive (a taxation of capital)
and a redistributive policy are required. We show
that a more egalitarian allocation is associated with
higher productive investment but reduced health
expenditure and thus, lower population growth.
1|INTRODUCTION
The state of human reproductive health has been one important debate in medical sciences in
recent years. The issue raised by a bench of papers concerns the natural ability for a couple to
have a child since it has been observed that infertility affects around 9% of procreatingaged
couples worldwide (Inhorn & Patrizio, 2015).
Regarding this question, we draw the reader's attention that it differs from fertility issues
generally addressed in the economic literature. Indeed, following the BarroBecker analysis
(1989), a huge literature has developed on the economic determinants of fertility, that is the
number of children a household chooses to have. Some papers, among others, have focused on
the qualityquantity tradeoff to justify the negative relationship between fertility and economic
growth; others dealt with the development of a unified growth theory that allows to understand
the demographic transition (Galor & Weil, 2000); others are more interested in fertility dif-
ferentials to better figure out economic inequalities (De la Croix & Doepke, 2003). In this paper,
we study equity in a model with undesired infertility.
Our concern focuses on biological impairments that prevent couples to reproduce, based on
relevant measures of human fertility, independently from individual choices. The deterioration
of human reproductive health has been widely documented from a functional perspective in the
epidemiological literature. Many studies point out the decline in men semen quality since the
beginning of the 20th century, the expanding Time To Pregnancy or the prevalence of new
female complex reproductive disorders (like endometriosis, ovarian quality, etc.), independent
of the agerelated natural decline in women fertility. For instance, following the seminal paper
by Carlsen, Giwercman, Keiding, and Skakkebk (1992) that gave birth to the famous falling
sperm countsstory, many studies have established a global declining quality of the sperma-
togenis. Figure 1illustrates some trends established in the literature, using one specific bio
marker for male fertility. As for women reproductive health, there are ongoing research with
respect to the use of biomarkers like antral follicular count and antimuëllerian hormone
(Nelson, 2013). Meanwhile, a recent epidemiological literature has studied the prevalence of
endocrine disorders like polycystic ovarian symptoms (PCOs) or diagnosed endometriosis
which are among the main causes of infertility. For instance, March et al. (2010) show that
PCOs are diagnosed for around 15% or more of reproductiveaged women.
All these compelling evidence raise concerns that the reproductive health at a couple level
could fall below some threshold levels that could impact fecundity, since those biomarkers and
diseases are suitable indicators of chances to parenthood. In addition and crucial to our ana-
lysis, these studies that point out a rapid change in human reproductive health cover periods of
fast economic development. Hence, we argue that postindustrial societies have created the
potential for increasing the exposure to specific lifestyle factors that might impair reproductive
health. Among them, one can identify pollution or diet that might contribute to explain
the current worldwide infertility and came along with the development process. We may find in
the epidemiological literature many studies to support our view and that have long suggested
FIGURE 1 Evolution of sperm concentration. Data from Borges et al. (2015), Carlsen et al. (1992), Huang
et al. (2017), Lackner et al. (2005), Levine et al. (2017), Rolland et al. (2013), RomeroOtero et al. (2015)
1214
|
ETNER ET AL.
adverse effects of exposure to environmental contaminants, such as persistent organic pollu-
tants, on men and women reproductive health.
1
Moreover, parenthood is a source of wellbeing and we should be concerned that some
couples can not reproduce.
2
To satisfy their desire of parenthood, some agents may be
compelled to use costly medical services like Assisted Reproductive Technology (ART). For
instance, since 2000, ART cycles annually grows by 5%10% in developed countries (Kupka
et al., 2016). This reduced ability to conceive children may be also costly to overcome for the
society. As shown by Chambers, Sullivan, Ishihara, Chapman, and Adamson (2009), the use
of ARTs represents substantial outofpocket health expenses. The estimated cost of a
standard in vitro fecundation (IVF) cycle ranges from 28% of Gross National Income (GNI)
per capita in the United States to 10% of GNI per capita in Japan. Also before any public
policy, the gross cost of a standard IVF cycle ranges from 50% of an individual's annual
disposable income in the United States, approximately 20% in the UK, Scandinavian coun-
tries and Australia, to 12% in Japan.
In our paper, we propose to explore the welfare inequalities induced by a health het-
erogeneity since infertility entails a loss of utility. What matters to us is the unfair feature of
such a health heterogeneity because agents are not totally responsible for their reproductive
health status. This is true if we think, for instance, to intrautero pollution exposure or living
conditions during childhood. We consider an overlapping generations model in which the
development process generates an externality as a form of a health heterogeneity: two types
of households coexist within one generation, the fertile and infertile households. Moreover,
exante infertile couples incur health treatments to increase their chances of parenthood.
Hence, the laissezfaire economy is characterized by several externalities: beyond the
oligodendrocytes (OLG)induced inefficiency, the accumulation of capital slackens
population growth meanwhile health care spending create positive external effects on the
demographic dynamics.
We aim at discussing the efficient way to correct these externalities in the long term. At first,
we consider the usual utilitarian social objective, but in contrast to Renström and Spataro
(2019), we do not restrict our attention to a welfarist approach, even though they enrich it with
a critical level of utility. Indeed, in the utilitarian case, health inequalities still prevail and we
can be concerned that the utility of the fertile is larger than the utility of the exante infertile.
Because heterogeneity is not the result of any actions held by agents but rather due to cir-
cumstances (let us refer for instance to pollution exposure), we also explore alternative criteria
of social evaluation according to Fleurbaey (2008), Ponthière (2016), or Fleurbaey, Leroux,
Pestieau, Ponthière, and Zuber (2018). More precisely, we consider an inequality averse social
planner who either maximizes the expected longrun wellbeing of the worstoff (exante ega-
litarian social criteria) or maximizes the longrun realized wellbeing of the worstoff (expost
egalitarian social criteria).
Our results drive us to formulate some policy recommendations. To rule out inefficiencies,
capital accumulation should be taxed. We argue that this preventive policy should be favored
1
See for instance Mendola, Messer, and Rappazzo (2008), RecioVega, OcampoGomez, BorjaAburto, MoranMartinez,
and CebrianGarcia (2008), Perry et al. (2011), Martenies and Perry (2013), Slama et al. (2013), Mehrpour, Karrari,
Zamani, Tsatsakis, and Abdollahi (2014), Zhou et al. (2014), Chiu et al. (2015), Bolden, Rochester, Schultz, and
Kwiatkowski (2017), or Sifakis, Androutsopoulos, Tsatsakis, and Spandidos (2017).
2
The distress associated with subfertility or treatments of infertility causes induces substantial sociopsychological costs,
like a severe degradation of selfesteem, syndromes of depression, loss of gender identity, selfassessed social pressure
from families, friendships, and so forth (Greil, 1997; MouraRamos, Gameiro, Canavarro, & Soares, 2012).
ETNER ET AL.
|
1215

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT