Regulation of Investments in Infrastructure: The Interplay between Strategic Behaviors and Initial Endowments

AuthorCHARLES FIGUIÈRES,MABEL TIDBALL,DENIS CLAUDE
Date01 February 2012
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9779.2011.01528.x
Published date01 February 2012
REGULATION OF INVESTMENTS IN INFRASTRUCTURE:
THE INTERPLAY BETWEEN STRATEGIC BEHAVIORS
AND INITIAL ENDOWMENTS
DENIS CLAUDE
CNRS CES
CHARLES FIGUI `
ERES
INRA LAMETA
MABEL TIDBALL
INRA LAMETA
Abstract
This paper explores the dynamic properties of price-based
policies in a model of competition between two jurisdic-
tions. Jurisdictions invest over time in infrastructure to in-
crease the quality of the environment, a global public good.
They are identical in all respects but one: initial stocks of in-
frastructure. This is a dynamic type of heterogeneity that dis-
appears in the long run. Therefore, at the steady state, usual
intuitions from static settings apply: identical jurisdictions
inefficiently underinvest, calling for public subsidies. In the
short run, however, counterintuitive properties are estab-
lished: (i) the evolution of capital stocks can be nonmono-
tonic and (ii) one jurisdiction can be temporarily taxed,
even though it should increase its investment, whereas the
other is subsidized. It is shown how these phenomena are
Denis Claude, Centre d’Economie de la Sorbonne, Maison des Sciences Economiques,
106–112 Boulevard de l’Hˆ
opital, 75647 Paris Cedex 13, France. Charles Figui`
eres, INRA
LAMETA, 2 Place Viala, 34060 Montpellier, France (charles.figuieres@supagro.inra.fr).
Mabel Tidball, INRA LAMETA, 2 Place Viala, 34060 Montpellier Cedex 1, France
(tidball@supagro.inra.fr).
Weare grateful for financial assistance from NSERC Canada. We thank Alain Jean-Marie,
Erik Ansik, Ngo Van Long, and Georges Zaccour for helpful comments. Also, we thank
participants at the 15th Annual Conference of the EAERE and 7th Meeting on Game
Theory and Practice for helpful discussions. Finally, many thanks are due to an Associate
Editor of JPET and two anonymous referees for very useful comments and suggestions on
a previous version of this work. The usual disclaimer applies.
Received July 20, 2008; Accepted September 28, 2010.
C
2012 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Public Economic Theory, 14 (1), 2012, pp. 35–66.
35
36 Journal of Public Economic Theory
related to initial conditions and the kind of interactions
between infrastructure capitals, complementarity or substi-
tutability.
1. Introduction
In recent years, the theoretical analysis of price-based policies for the control
of environmental externalities under imperfect competition has received a
renewed attention (see Requate 2006 for a survey). Previously, most of the
literature focused on the design of optimal tax or subsidy policies in a static
setting where several instantaneous effects of these instruments should be
balanced, e.g., with respect to taxation, the gain in terms of social welfare
arising from the reduction of pollution emissions against the loss from out-
put restriction.
However, little is known about how intertemporal externalities affect the
design and dynamic properties of price-based policies. Introducing the time
dimension raises the critical issue of credibility of public policies, namely,
how regulations should be framed to ensure that they remain optimal
in their ability to achieve social efficiency as circumstances change over
time. Such an explicit consideration of credibility requirements may qualify
substantially the intuitions about price-based regulations gained in a static
setting and may provide interesting and sometimes counterintuitive policy
advices.
An important contribution to this literature is Benchekroun and Van
Long (1998). They consider the efficiency-inducing taxation1for the regu-
lation of an oligopolistic industry which is responsible for releasing a stock
pollutant—one for which pollution accumulation generates present as well
as long-term environmental damages. They formulate a differential game of
pollution control in which the environmental regulator imposes a taxation
rule in a symmetric oligopolistic industry. In this game, the state variable is
the pollution stock, the tax policy is the control of the environmental regu-
lator, and output decisions are the controls of the firms which are assumed
to use either open-loop or Markov strategies.
Benchekroun and Van Long (1998) analyze a Markovian tax policy
whereby the output tax rate faced by a firm at any given time depends solely
on the current pollution stock. By construction, such an instrument is cred-
ible in the strong sense, i.e., it is subgame perfect. The authors provide a
characterization of the optimal tax rule that is shown to be increasing in the
pollution stock and to “decentralize” the socially optimal time path of pro-
duction. As for the dynamic properties of the tax, they obtain a surprising
result. In an initial time interval where the stock of pollution is low, the tax
rate may be negative implying a subsidy. Paradoxically, this subsidy induces
1On efficiency-inducing taxation, see also Bergstrom, Cross, and Porter (1981), Karp and
Livernois (1992), Ko, Lapan, and Sandler (1992), Karp and Livernois (1994), and Legras
(2010).
Regulation of Investments in Infrastructure 37
the firms to produce less than they would have if the industry had not been
regulated. Upon reflection, the explanation for this result is clear. Since the
tax rate at any given time depends solely on the pollution stock, firms antic-
ipate that an increase in their production will lead to reduced subsidies in
the future, and eventually precipitate the turn of the subsidy into a tax. As
noted by Benchekroun and Van Long (1998), this is an instance of “carrot
and stick” policy.
Motivated by a long standing concern for infrastructure competition,
this paper elaborates on Benchekroun and Van Long’s (1998) seminal con-
tribution by studying how differences in initial stocks of infrastructure alter
the dynamic properties of the optimal and credible tax or subsidy policy.
We consider a stylized dynamic extension of the model of interjurisdictional
spillovers introduced by Wildasin (1991). The focus of our attention is on
two jurisdictions located in the same watershed or airshed.2Each jurisdic-
tion invests in public (or green) infrastructure3in order to provide a public
good to its own residents. However, the public good produced by one ju-
risdiction also benefits the residents in the other jurisdiction who cannot
be excluded from “its” consumption once it is provided.4In the absence of
any regulation initiative, the presence of positive interjurisdictional spillovers
will result in the underprovision of public infrastructure. Indeed, local ju-
risdictions will not take into account the positive spillovers that benefit the
nonresidents when setting their investment policies. A first remedy is to
elevate the decision-making process to a higher level of jurisdiction so
that external benefits of public infrastructure become internal to the
2Here, we depart from the original meaning of the terms “watershed” and “airshed” and
adopt the North American usage in which they have come to describe the geographical
boundary for water and air quality standards.
3Most confusingly, the term “green infrastructure” is often used to refer to different en-
vironmental management solutions. Following Benedict and MacMahon (2002), the en-
vironmental conservation literature defines green infrastructure as “an interconnected
network of green space that conserves natural ecosystem values and functions and pro-
vides associated benefits to human populations.” However, it is not uncommon to use this
term to refer to engineered systems that mimic nature in function (e.g., porous pave-
ments or biological wastewater treatment facilities) or even all conventional engineered
systems aimed at environmental conservation (e.g., traditional wastewater treatment facili-
ties). In this paper, we adopt the latter usage, and define “green infrastructure” as an array
of products, technologies, and practices, relying on either natural or engineered systems,
that a local public authority can use to improve environmental quality.Furthermore, as the
model is abstract enough to cover a broad range of publicly funded goods with positive
externalities, we shall use the terms “public” and “green,” interchangeably.
4The prototypical situation we have in mind is the planning and development of the
Green-Blue Meander in the Netherlands. This major project aims at the creation of a
strong ecological and recreational buffer zone in the Randstad area, covering more than
200 km2of land between Rotterdam and The Hague. Responsibilities are divided as fol-
lows: (i) the Dutch government provides funding for the project, (ii) Rotterdam and The
Hague are in charge of land acquisition and conversion decisions, and (iii) the province
of South-Holland is responsible for the coordination of the decisions taken by the two
agglomerations.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT