Regulated Competition under Increasing Returns to Scale

Published date01 June 2016
Date01 June 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12172
REGULATED COMPETITION UNDER INCREASING RETURNS
TO SCALE
THOMAS GREVE
University of Cambridge
HANS KEIDING
University of Copenhagen
Abstract
In the classical models of regulation economics, a mechanism that se-
cures truthful revelation involves paying a subsidy to the firm. In this
paper, we investigate whether it is possible to create a regulatory mech-
anism under a no-subsidy constraint that induces the firm to report its
private information truthfully. We consider a number of firms operat-
ing under regulated competition and with increasing returns to scale
technology. It is shown that in equilibrium each firm chooses to report
truthfully without receiving any subsidy. The use of competition may
give rise to an efficiency loss due to the increasing returns to scale.
However, we show that our mechanism may still be better, from a so-
cial welfare point of view, than the case of monopoly regulation that
involves no subsidy.
1. Introduction
The interest in regulation of markets characterized by either monopoly or oligopoly
has a long history (see, e.g., the survey by Armstrong and Sappington 2007), and the
privatization of industries formerly owned and managed by governments, mainly in the
field of public utilities, has promoted an increased concern about regulation, often in
a context of market failures in the form of increasing returns to scale or asymmetric
information.
In this paper we consider such a case, where there are increasing returns to scale in
production. In the context of public utilities, this may occur for companies providing
services to the consumer (such as electricity or natural gas) which they either produce
themselves or acquire in a market where large buyers obtain considerable rebates. As is
well known, optimal allocation in a market with increasing returns to scale occurs at a
level of output where price equals marginal cost, so that pricing according to marginal
cost (see, e.g., Joskow 1976) can be sustained only if the producers are paid a subsidy.
Thomas Greve, University of Cambridge, Cambridge, CB3 9DD, U.K. (tg336@cam.ac.uk). Hans Kei-
ding, Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen, Oster Farimagsgade 5, DK-1353 Copen-
hagen K, Denmark (hans.keiding@econ.ku.dk).
Received September 30, 2013; Accepted September 15, 2015.
C2016 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Public Economic Theory, 18 (3), 2016, pp. 327–345.
327
328 Journal of Public Economic Theory
Throughout this paper, we assume that subsidization of producers is not possible,
so that the welfare optimum cannot be achieved. We shall not discuss reasons for or
justification of this assumption, which is taken as given here as in many other contexts,
such as, e.g., the theory of Ramsey pricing (cf. Hagen and Sheshinski 1986). Even so,
regulation serves the purpose of achieving an allocation which is welfare-superior to
monopoly or to an oligopolistic equilibrium for the case with more than one firm.
In particular, we shall compare regulation of a single firm, a monopoly, with a reg-
ulated competition between two firms, under the conditions of increasing returns to
scale and no subsidization. This comparison is not altogether trivial, since on the one
hand, the increasing returns to scale tend to favor production in a single plant, but on
the other hand the competition between two firms may lead to lower prices and larger
output.
As mentioned above, we shall assume that there is asymmetric information about
production cost which is private information for the firm in the case of monopoly and
for each firm if there are several firms. Thus the regulator must try to overcome the
informational advantage of the firm (or firms). In the case of a single firm, this takes
us to the theory of regulated monopoly, now under conditions of increasing returns
to scale.
There is a considerable literature on regulation of monopolies under asymmetric
information. In Loeb and Magat (1979), subsidies are used as incentives to surpass
the information asymmetry. Baron and Myerson (1982) present a mechanism that
induces the regulated monopoly to report its cost truthfully. We shall use the ideas of
Baron and Myerson in our treatment of regulated monopoly, but because subsidization
is not allowed the regulation which emerges cannot implement a welfare optimum,
and truthful revelation is obtained by allowing the firm a profit which is no less than
what could be achieved by misinformation of the regulator. The loss of welfare due to
smaller output and to the deliberate closing down of production when cost is too high
may be considerable.
As an alternative to the regulated monopoly, we then consider a case with two firms
both engaged in production, a regulated duopoly. Since we have increasing returns to
scale, a marginal cost equilibrium, where price equals marginal cost in each of the two
firms, would entail negative profits in both firms, and negative profits in at least one firm
if the regulator is free to redistribute profits between firms; thus, we cannot achieve a
welfare optimum in a regulated duopoly.1Accepting this, the regulation must come
as close to the welfare maximum as possible without subsidies, meaning that market
revenue should equal total cost of production, possibly with an acceptable profit mar-
gin. We consider one such regulation, where the firms are receiving regulated incomes
which allow for transfers of market profits from one firm to another but no overall sub-
sidization. However, the regulation depends on the level of cost of the two firms, which
is private information, and it is assumed that firms send messages about their true cost.
Having received the messages, the regulator proceeds according to the largest of the two
messages, but using regulated incomes which favor the firm with the smallest message.
It is shown that truthful revelation is an equilibrium; however, the firm with the lowest
cost can maintain an informational rent because the regulator acts as if both firms have
the higher cost.
1The result of Gradstein (1995) about the possibility of achieving a welfare optimum in regulated
oligopoly does not apply when there are increasing returns to scale, since it uses only the first-order
conditions for profit maximization, not taking into account the nonnegativity condition.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT