Regionalism as Industrial Policy: Evidence from MERCOSUR

Date01 February 2016
AuthorMarcel Vaillant,Pedro Moncarz,Marcelo Olarreaga
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12224
Published date01 February 2016
Regionalism as Industrial Policy: Evidence from
MERCOSUR
Pedro Moncarz, Marcelo Olarreaga, and Marcel Vaillant*
Abstract
This paper empirically explores whether trade preferences can be used as a substitute for industrial
policy and help countries achieve their industrialization objectives at the expense of other regional
members. Results show that Mercado Com
un del Sur (MERCOSUR) preferences obtained by Brazilian
exporters have led to an increase in exports of relatively sophisticated products in which Brazil does not
enjoy a global comparative advantage. On the contrary, smaller members of MERCOSUR export to the
region products in which they have strong comparative advantages and with relatively low levels of
sophistication. This suggests that MERCOSUR has helped Brazil achieve its industrialization objectives,
but has not contributed to the industrialization of its smaller members.
1. Introduction
The early economic literature on regionalism worried very little about its impact on
the multilateral system [perhaps because of the relative weakness of the General
Agreement on Trades and TariffsWorld Trade Organization (GATTWTO)
system at the time] and focused rather on the conditions under which regional
blocks are likely to enhance world and the block’s welfare (Viner, 1950; Kemp and
Wan, 1976; Panagariya and Krishna, 2002; Ohyama, 2007). A small part of this
literature looked at the distribution of gains within regional blocks.
1
An example of
this approach is Cooper and Massell (1965) where they argue that regional
integration schemes among developing countries could be used to achieve
industrialization objectives in the spirit of Prebisch (1959) at a smaller economic or
efficiency cost for their members. The idea is simple: facing a larger regional
demand through regional preferences, member countries can specialize their
industrial production in a smaller range of industrial products in which they are
relatively more competitive. Thus, the exogenous or politically determined level of
industrial production can be reached at a lower cost thanks to the creation of a
larger regional market.
2
One problem recognized by Cooper and Massell (1965) is that depending on the
cost structure of block members and the external protection structure chosen by
members of the regional block this may lead to the reallocation of industries within
*Olarreaga: University of Geneva, 40 Bd du Pont d’Arve, 1211, Geneva 4, Switzerland. Tel: +41-22-379-
8286; Fax: +41-22-379-8293; E-mail: marcelo.olarreaga@unige.ch. Moncarz: Facultad de Ciencias
Econ
omicas of Universidad Nacional de C
ordoba and CONICET, C
ordoba, Argentina. Vaillant:
Universidad de la Rep
ublica, Montevideo, Uruguay. The authors are grateful to participants of seminars
at the World Bank and Murphy Institute conference on the BRICs in New Orleans, the European Trade
Study Group meetings in Rome, the Fourth UNCTAD Virtual Institute Meeting in Geneva, the
Jornadas de Econom
ıa of the Central Bank of Uruguay, the IX Arnoldshain Seminar in Punta del Este,
and an anonymous referee for their constructive comments. We would also like to thank the UNCTAD
Virtual Institute’s joint research project on regional integration and cooperation in Latin America for
their support.
Review of Development Economics, 20(1), 359–373, 2016
DOI:10.1111/rode.12224
©2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT