Reflections on Matsushita and 'Equilibrating Tendencies': Lessons for Competition Authorities

AuthorStephen Calkins
PositionProfessor of Law, Wayne State University
Pages15-46
REFLECTIONS ON MATSUSHITA AND
“EQUILIBRATING TENDENCIES”:
LESSONS FOR COMPETITION AUTHORITIES
S
TEPHEN
C
ALKINS
*
Sometimes the simplest points are best. And it was a simple point that I
made in my fraternal twin publications on “equilibrating tendencies in the
antitrust system”:
1
In a system of law, as in nature, changes do not occur in a vacuum. Changes
to one part of a legal system may stimulate compensating adjustments else-
where, and the equilibrium position will depend both on the initial action
and on the legal system’s reaction. Attention to the initial changes alone
will conceal their likely ultimate consequences.
2
This article looks back on equilibrating tendencies and Matsushita’s
3
role in
them and looks briefly at current developments and particularly across the
pond to the European Union. It then sets forth several lessons for competition
agencies arising from consideration of equilibrating tendencies.
* Professor of Law, Wayne State University. This article draws on my experiences as a Mem-
ber of Ireland’s Competition and Consumer Protection Commission and its predecessor institu-
tion, the Competition Authority, and as General Counsel of the U.S. Federal Trade Commission,
but all views expressed herein are exclusively my own. For the avoidance of doubt—a great Irish
expression—I am not speaking on behalf of any Irish or American agency, and although many of
my examples will be American, the suggestions made are quite generally applicable.
1
Stephen Calkins, Summary Judgment, Motions to Dismiss, and Other Examples of Equili-
brating Tendencies in the Antitrust System, 74 G
EO
. L.J. 1065 (1986) [hereinafter Calkins, Equi-
librating Tendencies]; Stephen Calkins, Equilibrating Tendencies in the Antitrust System, with
Special Attention to Summary Judgment and to Motions to Dismiss, in P
RIVATE
A
NTITRUST
L
ITI-
GATION
: N
EW
E
VIDENCE
, N
EW
L
EARNING
185 (Lawrence J. White ed., 1988). The two publica-
tions both derived from a paper I presented at the Georgetown project on private antitrust
litigation and made largely the same points. I will refer to the law review version because it is
more generally accessible. I continue to be grateful to Robert Pitofsky for his role in sponsoring
my participation in such a rewarding project.
2
Calkins, Equilibrating Tendencies, supra note 1, at 1066.
3
Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574 (1986).
15
82 Antitrust Law Journal No. 1 (2018). Copyright 2018 American Bar Association. Reproduced
by permission. All rights reserved. This information or any por tion thereof may not be copied
or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or stored in an electronic
database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar
Association.
16
A
NTITRUST
L
AW
J
OURNAL
[Vol. 82
I. A LOOK BACK
My article gave concrete examples of equilibrating tendencies. For in-
stance, a severe penal code will be mitigated by the stretching of rules to favor
defendants, while, in torts, if even trivial negligence on the part of a plaintiff
will bar recovery, courts will strive to avoid injustice by erecting a series of
exceptions.
4
Then, if the stringent substantive law is relaxed, the legal system
can readjust.
Or, to use a competition example, if the simple finding of a vertical agree-
ment to maintain prices automatically results in liability, treble damages, and
attorneys’ fees—regardless of power, regardless of effect, regardless of justi-
fication, and regardless of growing uncertainty about just how harmful resale
price maintenance (RPM) really is—do not be surprised if the legal system
responds by making it incredibly hard to prove an agreement.
5
As my article explained, antitrust offers a host of examples of equilibrating
tendencies at work. Substantive U.S. antitrust simply is different because of
the (un)holy trinity of treble damages, attorneys’ fees, and liberal discovery
(not to mention class actions and jury trials). One can see the influence not
only in substantive but also in procedural law. (Consider, for instance, the
challenge of proving standing and antitrust injury.
6
)
A.
M
ONSANTO
The classic example is provided by Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service
Corp.
7
It is one of American antitrust’s best-known cases, but the case is
worth reviewing in part to aid non-experts on U.S. law and also in part to
ensure that the words “evidence that tends to exclude the possibility” are fully
appreciated.
In 1977 the Court had relaxed the substantive rules governing vertical re-
straints, making all non-price restraints subject to the rule of reason while
preserving the per se ban on vertical price agreements.
8
(Some Justices—and
the Solicitor General—would have gone further and judged all vertical re-
4
Calkins, Equilibrating Tendencies, supra note 1, at 1067–71, 1075 –79.
5
See id. at 1094.
6
See id. at 1101–04.
7
Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Serv. Corp, 465 U.S. 752 (1984).
8
Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 51 n.18 (1977) (“As in Schwinn,
we are concerned here only with nonprice vertical restrictions. The per se illegality of price
restrictions has been established firmly for many years and involves significantly different ques-
tions of analysis and policy.”). Justice White, concurring, accurately perceived that the Court was
taking a step down a slippery slope because “[i]t is common ground among the leading advocates
of a purely economic approach to the question of distribution restraints that the economic argu-
ments in favor of allowing vertical nonprice restraints generally apply to vertical price restraints
as well.” Id. at 69 (White, J., concurring). He presciently observed that “[t]he effect, if not the
2018]
M
ATSUSHITA
AND
“E
QUILIBRATING
T
ENDENCIES
17
straints under the rule of reason.
9
) This meant, according to the Monsanto
Court, that it was “of considerable importance that independent action by the
manufacturer, and concerted action on nonprice restrictions, be distinguished
from price-fixing agreements, since under present law the latter are subject to
per se treatment and treble damages.”
10
And it was important to prevent an
RPM agreement from being inferred “from highly ambiguous evidence.”
What was the “highly ambiguous evidence” that troubled the Court? Evi-
dence that a manufacturer terminated a large
11
discounting dealer
12
after re-
ceiving and “‘in response to’ ” complaints from rival dealers.
13
The evidence
was strong enough that a jury found that plaintiff Spray-Rite was terminated
“‘pursuant to a conspiracy . . . with one or more of [Monsanto’s] distributors
to fix, maintain or stabilize resale prices.’”
14
It was strong enough that the
Seventh Circuit Court of Appeals unanimously affirmed and rehearing en
banc was denied.
15
That court held: “Proof of distributorship termination in
response to competing distributors’ complaints about the terminated distribu-
tor’s pricing policies is sufficient to raise an inference of concerted action.”
16
It pointed to “numerous complaints from competing Monsanto distributors
about Spray-Rite’s price-cutting practices” and testimony by a Monsanto offi-
cial “that Spray-Rite was terminated because of the price complaints.”
17
This was not sufficient for the Supreme Court. “Permitting an agreement to
be inferred merely from the existence of complaints, or even from the fact that
termination came about ‘in response to’ complaints, could deter or penalize
intention, of the Court’s opinion is necessarily to call into question the firmly established per se
rule against price restraints.” Id. at 70.
9
See Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 761 n.7 (“The Solicitor General (by brief only) and several other
amici suggest that we take this opportunity to reconsider whether [agreements] . .. to fix resale
prices should always be unlawful. They argue that the economic effect of resale price mainte-
nance is little different from agreements on nonprice restrictions. They say that the economic
objections to resale price maintenance that we discussed in Sylvania—such as that it facilitates
horizontal cartels—can be met easily in the context of rule-of-reason analysis.... We ... decline
to reach the question, and we decide the case in the context in which it was decided below and
argued here.”) (citations omitted).
10
Id. at 763; see also id. at 764 (“In sum, ‘[t]o permit the inference of concerted action on the
basis of receiving complaints alone and thus to expose the defendant to treble damage liability
would both inhibit management’s exercise of independent business judgment and emasculate the
terms of the statute.’” (alteration in original) (quoting Edward J. Sweeney & Sons, Inc. v. Tex-
aco, Inc., 637 F.2d 105, 111 n.2 (3d Cir. 1980))).
11
“Spray-Rite was the 10th largest out of approximately 100 distributors of Monsanto’s pri-
mary corn herbicide.” Id. at 757.
12
“Spray-Rite was a discount operation, buying in large quantities and selling at a low mar-
gin.” Id. at 756.
13
Id. at 759.
14
Id. at 758 n.2 (quoting special interrogatory).
15
Spray-Rite Serv. Corp. v. Monsanto Co., 684 F.2d 1226 (7th Cir. 1982).
16
Id. at 1239.
17
Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 759.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT