Redistributive innovation policy, inequality, and efficiency

Published date01 June 2020
AuthorParantap Basu,Yoseph Getachew
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12386
Date01 June 2020
J Public Econ Theory. 2020;22:532554.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet532
|
© 2019 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Received: 8 January 2019
|
Accepted: 6 June 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12386
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Redistributive innovation policy, inequality,
and efficiency
Parantap Basu
1
|
Yoseph Getachew
2
1
Department of Economics and Finance,
Durham University Business School
Durham University, Durham, UK
2
Department of Economics, University
of Pretoria, Pretoria, South Africa
Correspondence
Yoseph Getachew, Department of
Economics, University of Pretoria,
Pretoria 0028, South Africa.
Email: yoseph.getachew@up.ac.za
Abstract
We examine the efficiency and distributional effects of
regressive and progressive public R&D policies that
target hightech and lowtech sectors using a hetero-
genousagent growth model with inhouse R&D and
incomplete capital markets. We find that such policies
have important implications for efficiency and inequal-
ity. A regressive public R&D investment financed by
income tax could boost growth and welfare via a
positive effect on individual savings and effort. It could,
however, also lower growth and welfare via its effect on
the efficiencyinequality tradeoff. Thus, the relation-
ship between public R&D spending and welfare is
humpshaped, admitting an optimal degree of regressiv-
ity in public R&D spending. Using our baseline model,
and the US statelevel GDP data, we derive the degree of
regressiveness of public R&D investment in US states.
We find that US states are more regressive in their R&D
investment than the optimal regressiveness implied by
our growth model.
KEYWORDS
growth, inequality dynamics, public R&D investment, welfare
JEL CLASSIFICATION
D31; E13; H4; O41
1
|
INTRODUCTION
The role of public and private research and development (R&D) investment
1
in economic
growth is a widely debated topic.
2
However, the distributional effect of public R&D investment
has received little attention. In the extant literature, the focus is more on public education (e.g.,
Benabou, 2002; Glomm & Ravikumar, 1992, 2003), globalization (e.g., Bontems & Gozlan, 2018)
and infrastructure and taxes (e.g., Alesina & Rodrik, 1994; Chatterjee & Turnovsky, 2012;
GarciaPenalosa & Turnovsky, 2007; Getachew, 2010; Getachew & Turnovsky, 2015). R&D
investment could have uneven impacts on the economy and, through this channel, could
impact rich and poor differently. In general, most public R&D investment in developed
countries is concentrated on hightech industries such as information technology, biotechnol-
ogy, communication, and environment industries. In the United States, for instance, public
R&D investment in equipment and software has increased from 20% in 1980 to 50% in 2001,
which contributed to rising inequality in the United States in recent decades (Cozzi &
Impullitti, 2010). R&D investment in South Korea is concentrated more on hightech sectors
(Kim, Chun, & Kim, 2013). In contrast, in most of the developing world, a significant amount of
public R&D investments are made in agriculture, a lowtech sector dominated by smallscale
farmers. Beintema, Stads, Fuglie, and Heisey (2012) report an accelerated public investment in
agricultural R&D in developing countries during the period 2000 and 2008. Using provincial
data in China spanning more than four decades, Zhang and Fan (2004) argue that government
spending on agricultural R&D contributed to a reduction in regional inequality.
Our own calculations suggest a contrasting relationship between inequality and public R&D
spending, consistent with previous studies. Figures 1 and 2 show the relationships between the
GINI index and R&D intensity in the United States and public R&D spending in subSaharan
Africa (SSA), respectively.
3
In both regions, R&D spending has sharply increased during the last
two decades, but the inequality experience is the opposite.
4
While there is a positive correlation
between GINI and R&D investment across US states, for SSA countries; however, the
correlation is negative. Given that R&D spending in the United States is more geared to
the hightech sector while in SSA it is primarily focused on subsistence farming, this reversal of
the sign of the correlation, between R&D intensity and the GINI, between Figures 1 and 2 is
intriguing. Inequality could result from public R&D investment due to its destination.
The key research question in this paper is therefore whether the public R&D spending is
likely to be regressive or progressive. The effects of public R&D investment on efficiency and
inequality are therefore examined using the lens of a heterogenousagent growth model, where
agents are heterogenous in their initial endowments of knowledge and their ability to generate
knowledge. The model includes inhouse R&D which yields monopolistic profit for the firms.
Both inequality and growth are endogenously determined. The source of endogenous growth is
inhouse R&D investment using private and public resources. Endogenous inequality is
1
R&D expenditure includes a broad range of activities: Research and development (R&D) comprise creative work undertaken on a systematic basis in order to
increase the stock of knowledge (including knowledge of man, culture and society) and the use of this knowledge to devise new applications.(http://
www.oecd.org/sdd/08_Science_and_technology.pdf).
2
Particularly, in early 1990s, there was an influx of R&Dbased growth theories, following the seminal works by Romer (1990), Grossman and Helpman (1991),
and Aghion and Howitt (1992) that emphasize the role of R&D in economic growth, through influencing technological progress. R&D policies are also widely
debated as to whether public R&D investment complements private R&D investment or crowds it out (e.g., David, Hall, & Toole, 2000). Early work in public
R&D investment includes Shell (1967).
3
The R&D intensity is measured by the ratio of total R&D spending (including private and public GDP) to state GDP (gross domestic product). The breakdown
of public and private R&D for each state is not available. The National Science Foundations sources suggest that the Federal share of total R&D spendingis
about 11.6% over the period 20082015. All the GINI data came from US Census Bureau. The R&D intensity data came from the Science, Technology,
Innovation and Entrepreneurship (SSTI) database of the United States. The correlation coefficient between R&D Intensity and State GINI index is 0.18. For SSA
countries, the GINI and public R&D spending data came from World Bank (2015). Due to sparse nature of the data, we take the average of GINI index from
2000 onward whatever data are available. Same is done for the public R&D spending ratio. Details of all these data are available from the authors upon request.
4
The average annual agricultural R&D spending growth in SSA countries, for instance, increased from 0.3% during 19811990 to 2.8% during 20002008 except
for a small dip of 0.01% during 19902000, which is indicative of the bulk of recent R&D innovations in SSA being progressive in nature (Beintema et al., 2012).
BASU AND GETACHEW
|
533

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT