Redistributive Colonialism: The Long Term Legacy of International Conflict in India*

Published date01 June 2017
Date01 June 2017
DOI10.1177/0032329217705358
AuthorAlexander Lee
Subject MatterSpecial Issue Articles
https://doi.org/10.1177/0032329217705358
Politics & Society
2017, Vol. 45(2) 173 –224
© 2017 SAGE Publications
Reprints and permissions:
sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0032329217705358
journals.sagepub.com/home/pas
Special Issue Article
Redistributive Colonialism:
The Long Term Legacy
of International Conflict
in India*
Alexander Lee
University of Rochester
Abstract
The growth of European colonial empires occurred during a period of intense
international conflict. This article examines how the international position of
colonial states altered the distribution of wealth within indigenous societies. Colonial
administrators favored precolonial elites only if they were militarily and financially
secure, a pattern that stems from balancing the advantages of working with these
groups against their higher probability of revolt. This theory is tested using data
on the wealth of Indian caste groups. In areas annexed at times of European war,
precolonial elites are poorer than other groups, whereas they remain richer in areas
annexed at other times and in indirectly ruled areas. These results appear not to
stem from preexisting differences between regions. The results highlight the variable
impact of colonialism within societies, and the importance of the international system
in shaping colonial and postcolonial outcomes.
Keywords
colonialism, historical persistence, conflict
Corresponding Author:
Alexander Lee, University of Rochester, Harkness Hall, Rochester, NY 14627, USA.
Email: alexander.mark.lee@rochester.edu
*This special issue of Politics & Society titled “The Comparative Politics of Colonialism and Its Legacies”
features an introduction and four papers that were presented as part of a workshop held at The Ohio
State University, April 2016, organized by Marcus Kurtz and Jan Henryk Pierskalla.
705358PASXXX10.1177/0032329217705358Politics & SocietyLee
research-article2017
174 Politics & Society 45(2)
Numerous studies have shown that variation in colonial institutions can explain varia-
tion in contemporary economic and social outcomes.1 However, in their focus on the
effect of long-term institutional differences, these accounts have neglected the inter-
state rivalries and calculations into which colonial conquest was embedded. We have
little understanding of whether and how European political events and decisions, such
as the persistent wars that plagued early modern Europe, altered colonial policy.
Moreover, the existing literature on colonialism has focused on the aggregate
effects of policies such as indirect rule.2 However, as some of these authors recognize,
even within regions and nations, some social groups may benefit from colonial poli-
cies, such as taxation and government hiring, while others will be hurt by them, and
these differences may persist long after the official favoritism or distrust that gave rise
to them faded away. Such changes in internal social positioning may produce social
“reversals of fortune” just as dramatic as those we observe cross-nationally.3 This is
not to say that these distributional effects are unstudied: Case studies provide strong
evidence of colonial favoritism toward specific groups: The Belgians favored Tutsis
over Hutus in Rwanda, the British favored Tamils over Sinhalese in Sri Lanka, the
Spanish favored Tlaxcalans over Mexica in Mexico. Such favoritism is often thought
of as significant as a cause of later ethnic conflicts or social inequalities.4 However,
such single-country accounts leave open many questions, including three potentially
important ones: (1) why the process of colonialism systematically favored some
groups over others, (2) whether or not such favoritism actually altered existing pat-
terns of stratification, and (3) whether these effects have persisted to the present day.
This article suggests that relations between colonial administrators and Indian elites
varied with the diplomatic situation in Europe and the level of military pressure faced
by the colonial power. Somewhat counterintuitively, European conflict is associated
with disruption in local social patterns. In European wartime, colonial administrators
felt insecure militarily, and tended to view the precolonial elite (the most obvious lead-
ers of a revolt) with suspicion. Similarly, in wartime the fiscal pressure on the colonial
state was much greater, increasing its incentive to disfavor existing elites through
methods such as heavy taxation and biased hiring policies. In European peacetime, the
military and fiscal pressure on the colonial state was less intense, and the colonial state
found it more convenient to leave existing elites in place, borrowing their personnel
and (in indirectly ruled areas) their institutions. Incorporation into colonial institutions
in turn allowed these elite groups to maintain high levels of socioeconomic status.
These temporary patterns persisted over time because they created a self-sustain-
ing equilibrium. Annexation represented a critical juncture when colonial officials
were forced to make choices about local institutions: If precolonial officials, net-
works and institutional arrangements were eliminated during the annexation pro-
cess, they were impossible to reconstitute later. Moreover, any institutional
innovation created influential constituencies that made change more difficult at later
periods. British expropriation of local landholders, for instance, not only dissolved
the local networks of these landholders but created a new class of landholders eager
to cement their position. While many other political changes have occurred in India
since that time—land reform, democracy, and so on—wealthy and powerful groups
Lee 175
can retain these advantages despite political changes, either by accumulating diffi-
cult-to-expropriate human capital or manipulating institutional changes to their own
advantage.5 There is considerable evidence that Indian elites adapted both these tac-
tics after independence.6
In estimating the effect of European war at the time of annexation, an obvious
potential concern is that wartime annexation may be influenced by some attribute of
the units themselves, with colonial powers varying the type of territory they annex
based on geopolitical factors. There are theoretical reasons for thinking that biased
assignment is not a major problem in the Indian case: the dates of European wars were
decided in Europe rather than in India and annexation decisions tended to be highly
responsive to local political events. This is supported by the available data, since both
annexation and military conflict in India are uncorrelated with European conflict.
There is also strong support for the contention that areas annexed in European wartime
and European peacetime were similar in their social characteristics, since areas
annexed at times of European war appear very similar on geographical and social
observables to areas annexed at other times.
India, where there was considerable indigenous social stratification, and where the
colonial conquest was contemporaneous with a long series of on-and-off wars between
Britain and France, is an obvious place to test this theory. The question of cross-group
redistribution is particularly urgent in contemporary India, where intergroup economic
inequalities are very marked (today, 44 percent of modern variation in wealth can be
explained by caste).7 In particular, there is substantial variation in the economic posi-
tion of precolonial landed groups. The fact that landed castes do better economically
than other Indians is not particularly surprising, given the sizable head start that they
had over most other social groups. What is surprising is that there is sizable variation
in this economic advantage. For example, while precolonial landed groups have an
average household wealth .64 standard deviations higher than non-landed groups in
Bihar, they are slightly poorer than non-landed groups in the neighboring state of West
Bengal, which had similar formal colonial institutions and land tenure systems. This
variance has direct relevance for the lives of millions of Indians, who find themselves
richer or poorer than their neighbors. It has an even greater indirect relevance for the
politics and political economy of India, since many students of Indian politics, notably
Srinivas, and the contributors to Frankel and Rao,8 have traced variation in the politi-
cal performance of Indian states to the social position of landed caste groups.
The quantitative results show that while colonial-era wars have little impact on the
wealth of non-landed groups, they dramatically affect the wealth of landed ones. In
areas where there was no European war at the time of annexation, landholding groups
perform better economically than non-landholding groups. In areas annexed in war-
time, this advantage is reversed, with non-landed groups being relatively wealthier than
non-landed ones. While wars in India during annexation have similar effects on landed
elites to war in Europe, international conflict is an important predictor of local distribu-
tional patterns independent of local conflicts, whose intensity they tended to enhance.
An empirical strategy based on the time of annexation cannot be directly applied to the
large areas of India that were indirectly ruled. As the theory would expect, in these areas

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT