Recovery of Robinson–Patman Damages: Confusion and Resolution

Published date01 September 1986
Date01 September 1986
AuthorShik C. Young,David Bunting
DOI10.1177/0003603X8603100307
Subject MatterArticle
The Antitrust Bulletin/Fall 1986
Recovery
of
Robinson-Patman
damages: confusion and resolution
BY DAVID BUNTING* and SHIK C. YOUNG**
Introduction
797
In recent years, the Robinson-Patman Act has been heavily
attacked as misguided, anticompetitive, and theoretically un-
sound. According to Elzinga, the act sought to "preserve the
independent retailer, the so-called 'Mom and
Pop'
store" and to
"maintain an atmosphere for skit and whittle."IEconomic
theorists have found more holes in the act than in a screen door
while, for the legal profession, it "provides a full employment
program for antitrust lawyers and professors and provides comic
relief for law students."? Although the act should have been
repealed years ago, florists, candy sellers, liquor dealers, tire
retreaders, bakers, and assorted other "Moms and Pops" have
been able to fill the halls of Congress and block the nation's
Professor of Economics, Eastern Washington University, Cheney,
Washington.
•• Professor of Economics, Eastern Washington University, Cheney,
Washington.
IK. G. Elzinga, The Robinson-Patman Act: A New Deal
for
Small Business, in REGULATORY
CHANGE
IN AN ATMOSPHERE OF
CRISIS
66
(G. M. Walton ed. 1979).
2
[d.
at 67, quoting D. I. Baker, then a recent head of the Antitrust
Division of the Department of Justice.
© 1986by Federal Legal Publications, Inc.
798 The antitrust bulletin
march toward economic efficiency. But despite this outpouring
of
democratic sentiment, the Federal Trade Commission in a rare
instance
of
useful action has simply refused to enforce the act.'
While common, these opinions conceal as much as they
reveal. On the one hand, they implicitly assume that Robin-
son-Patman
cases invariably follow the
A&p4
motif, whereby
small, presumably inefficient buyers use the act to counteract
inherent efficiencies enjoyed by a large competitor as all bargain
with neutral sellers. Dreadful consequences will appear if these
"Moms and
Pops"
succeed: the inefficient will survive, econo-
mies will be denied, and society will be burdened with high prices
and misallocated resources. On the other hand, critics nearly
always base their views on FTC cases and ignore private attempts
and motivations to use the act. While it is correct that federal
enforcement has virtually ceased in recent years, attempts still
persist to use the act for private relief.
It
is in the sphere
of
private cases that many
of
the amusing
comments about the act can be disregarded as irrelevant. Rather
than
small firms seeking protection from the efficiency of some
large competitor, private cases invariably involve small buyers
seeking damages for the unfair actions
of
amonopoly seller who
favored competitors of the complaining buyers. These cases
clearly have their "Mom and
Pop"
aspect, but from another
perspective. On one side of the market is a large seller, usually of
abranded good like beer or gasoline. On the other side are many
small distributors, competing not only among themselves but
with similar, highly substitutable goods. Finally, the element
of
discrimination exists. For some reason, perhaps by design but
possibly by error or changing circumstances, the seller has
favored some buyers to the disadvantage of others.
[d. at 68.
4United States v. New York Great Atlantic and Pacific Tea Co.,
67 F. Supp. 626 (1946), 173 F.2d 79 (1949). For a vigorous and extensive
critique that has influenced ageneration of economists, see M. A.
ADELMAN,
A&P:
A
STUDY
IN
PRICE-COST
BEHAVIOR
AND
PUBLIC
POLICY
(1959).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT