Reciprocity, Monopsony Power, and Section 7

AuthorJerome L. Withered
DOI10.1177/0003603X8002500107
Published date01 March 1980
Date01 March 1980
Subject MatterArticle
The Antitrust Bulletin/Spring 1980
Reciprocity, monopsony
power, and section 7
BY
JEROME
L. WITHERED*
217
Since the passage of the Celler-Kefauver Act in 1950amending the
Clayton Act, mergers and acquisitions have been challenged by the
government on a wide variety
of
theories. One
of
the most con-
troversial is that a merger creates the probability
of
asubstantial
lessening
of
competition through the use of reciprocal buying ar-
rangements. This article will examine the economic impact
of
reci-
procity on the market and the tests applied by the federal courts in
construing section 7.I
*Associate; Dickson, Reiling &Teder, Lafayette, Indiana.
AUTHOR'S
NOTE:
This article is derived
from
my
M.A.
thesis in
economics at the University
of
Virginia.
ISection 7 of the amended Clayton Act, 15
U.S.c.
§18 (1970),
reads in part:
"That
no corporation engaged in commerce shall acquire, directly or
indirectly, the whole or any part of the stock or other share capital
and
no corporation subject to the jurisdiction of the Federal Trade
Commission shall acquire the whole or any
part
of the assets of
another
corporation engaged also in commerce, where in any line of
commerce in any section of the country, the effect of such acquisition
may be substantially to lessen competition, or to tend to create a
monopoly."
,c..,
1980by Federal Legal Publications, Inc.
218 : The antitrust bulletin
Economic
impact
Perhaps the simplest and most explicit definition
of
reciproc-
ity is that it is the practice
of
taking your business to whomever
brings business to you. In the context
of
most cases involving
section 7
of
the Clayton Act, the acquiring firm (or seller)
initially is buying products from another firm (supplier). The
seller then merges with or acquires asubsidiary that happens to
sell input products that the supplier must purchase to produce
its goods for sale. The reciprocal relationship develops as the
supplier begins to purchase inputs from the seller. 2
It
has been argued that there are three separate types of
reciprocity buying in the business world. The first is coercive
reciprocity where a seller, by threatening to withdraw orders
from asupplier firm, coerces that supplier into purchasing input
products from the seller or its subsidiary. The supplier, in order
to remain in business, relents to the threat and a reciprocal
arrangement develops. The other two forms
of
reciprocity are
voluntary commitments. Mutual patronage reciprocity is what is
commonly known as commercial back-scratching. The seller un-
dertakes an agreement to purchase the products
of
its supplier
in return for that supplier buying the products
of
the seller or
its subsidiary. Finally, in the case
of
defensive reciprocity.' the
supplier voluntarily purchases from the seller with the hope that
the seller will reciprocate by purchasing from the supplier.
2In that the major emphasis of the government's attack on the
practice
of
reciprocity has been in the merger field, this article will
consider only the reciprocity problem with regard to mergers under
section 7. Actions under the Sherman Act will not be considered.
However, the same technique can be used in a Sherman Act context
and the effects
of
the practice can be analyzed thereby. Compare
DeVoto v. Pacific Fidelity Life Ins.
Co.,
516 F.2d I (9th Cir. 1975),
cert, denied, 423 U.S. 894 (1976); U.S. v. Airco, Inc., 386 F.Supp.
915 (S.D. N.Y. 1974); and W.L. Gore &Associates, Inc. v. Carlisle
Corp., 381 F.Supp. 680 (D.Del. 1974), mod'd, 529 F.2d 614 (3d Cir.
1975) where the courts applied sections 1 &2 of the Sherman Act to
reciprocal buying situations.
JSometimes called reciprocity effect.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT