Real Rights of Noncompetition: Louisiana Public Policy and the Civil Tradition

AuthorAlex Hotard
PositionJ.D./D.C.L., 2017, Paul M. Hebert Law Center, Louisiana State University.
Pages1209-1248
Real Rights of Noncompetition: Louisiana Public
Policy and the Civil Tradition
INTRODUCTION
In 1985, James and Catherine Olinde, co-owners of a ten-acre tract of
land, decided to open a restaurant.1 They set aside four acres for their new
enterprise, Ralph & Kacoos Restaurant, and planned to sell the
remainder.2 The Olindes understood, however, that when any business
sells land there is a risk that it will fall into a competitor’s hands.3 The
couple protected themselves from this risk by including a noncompetition
clause in their act of sale: the land was sold to Anthony Diez on the
condition that it could not be used for the operation of a seafood restaurant
until 60 months after the sale.4 Shortly after the sale, Mr. Diez leased his
new land to a third party who promptly opened a seafood restaurant, and
the Olindes brought suit.5 This seemingly simple contract dispute belies a
labyrinth of jurisprudence, doctrine, and law, all surrounding Louisiana’s
real rights of noncompetition.
States universally recognize and regulate noncompetition agreements
to balance the needs of business with the needs of the public.6 The
arrangements can take a direct approach by restraining a person from
participating in commerce7 or an indirect approach by restraining the
commercial use of a particular property.8 The latter approach often arises
in lease agreements or sales of land.9 In many states, the breach of these
land-restricting agreements will give rise to action against not only the
owner who made the agreement, but also any lessees or subsequent
Copyright 2017, by ALEX HOTARD.
1. R & K Bluebonnet, Inc. v. Patout’s of Baton Rouge, Inc., 521 So. 2d 634,
635 (La. Ct. App. 1988).
2. Id.
3. Id.
4. Id.
5. Id.
6. E.g., LA. REV. STAT. § 23:921 (2017); MONT. CODE ANN. § 28-2-703
(2017); TEX. BUS. & COM. CODE ANN. § 15.50 (West 2015).
7. LA. REV. STAT. § 23:921 (permitting such agreements within certain
constraints).
8. Mark S. Dennison, Lessee’s Enforcement of Covenant Prohibiting Lessor’s
Use or Lease of Other Premises for Use in Competition With Lessee's Business, in
95 AM. JUR. PROOF OF FACTS 467, 476 (2007).
9. Id.
1210 LOUISIANA LAW REVIEW [Vol. 77
purchasers of the affected property.10 In Louisiana, however, it is not so
easy to enforce these land-restricting noncompetition agreements against
third parties.11
This difference is due to Louisiana’s division of rights and their
corresponding obligations into two categories: real and personal.12 Only real
rights, such as the right of ownership,13 follow property and can be enforced
against all third parties.14 Personal rights, such as the right to collect
payment, follow persons and can only be enforced against third parties who
have explicitly agreed to assume the obligation.15 The distinction between
real and personal rights is important for businesses seeking to limit the use
of property because it is far more effective to bind everyone who might ever
be associated with the property than to bind only the current owner of the
property.16 Savvy businesses, such as Ralph & Kacoos Restaurant,17 will
therefore attempt to create “real rights of noncompetition”18 in their land-
use-restricting contracts.
10. See Winn-Dixie Stores, Inc. v. Dolgencorp, LLC, 746 F.3d 1008, 1026
(11th Cir. 2014) (finding lease agreements bet ween the plaintiff and various
lessors in Florida that limited the space other tenants could use for the sale of
groceries created rights that were enforceable against co-tenants).
11. See, e.g., id. Winn Dixie sued to enforce lease agreements prohibiting
competition ac ross several states. Id. Winn Dixie’s contracts were enforceable
against its fellow lessors in Florida, but they were not enforceable against third
parties in Louisiana because of Louisiana’s distinction between real and personal
obligations. Id. at 1031.
12. See LA. CIV. CODE art. 1763 cmt. b (201 7) (stating that a real right is a
right enforceable against the whole world rather than against a single person); id.
art. 1763 (defining real obligations as those incidental to real rights). The terms
“personal right” and “personal obligation” are not d efined explicitly in the Code,
but they refer to those civil rights and obligations that are not “real rights” or “real
obligations.” See, e.g., id. art. 734 cmt. b; id. art. 1764 (establishing that personal
obligations are transferred only by explicit assumption of the personal obligation
by an obligor’s successor).
13. Id. art. 476 cmt. b.
14. Id. art. 1763 cmt. b (stating that a real right is a right enforceable against
the whole world rather than against a single person); id. art. 1764 (establishing
that real rights are transferred by transfer of an associated property).
15. See id. arts. 1764, 18211823; id. art. 1764 cmt. d.
16. This Louisiana quirk has already caused problems for at least one unwary
business. See Winn-Dixie, 746 F.3d at 1031.
17. R & K Bluebonnet, Inc. v. Patout’s of Baton Rouge, Inc., 521 So. 2d 634,
635 (La. Ct. App. 1988). See also Meadowcrest Ctr. v. Tenet Health Sys. Hosps.,
Inc., 902 So. 2d 512, 514 (La. Ct. App. 2005).
18. Because Louisiana calls any rights that run with property and affect third
parties “real rights,” see LA. CIV. CODE art. 1763 cmt. b; id. art. 1764, the term
2017] COMMENT 1211
The Louisiana Supreme Court has affirmed that land-restricting
noncompetition agreements can create personal rights and obligations,19 but
the Court has yet to address whether parties can create real rights of
noncompetition.20 Other Louisiana courts have generally upheld real rights
of noncompetition in the form of predial servitudes,21 but these decisions
rest on cursory legal analyses that gloss over the essential elements of
predial servitudes.22
Predial servitudes that restrict trade can provide protection to businesses
and encourage the sale of property, but there are two major obstacles to court
enforcement of these servitudes. First, most predial servitudes of
noncompetition are theoretically unsound under the Louisiana Civil Code
and civil law doctrine.23 Second, these arrangements can permanently
remove property from trade,24 even to the point that businesses might
purchase their own regional monopolies given enough wealth.25 If the
Louisiana legislature approves of real rights of noncompetition, there must
be legislation to authorize and regulate them.26
“real right of noncompetition” is a fitting description for the rights and obligations
discussed in this Comment. For reasons established in Part I of this Comment, this
term is interchangeable with “predial servitude of noncompetition.” See infra Part I.
19. See, e.g., Leonard v. Lavigne, 162 So. 2d 341, 343 (La. 1964).
20. A. N. YIANNOPOULOS, PREDIAL SERVITUDES § 6:5, in 4 LOUISIANA CIVIL
LAW TREATISE 357 (4th ed. 2013).
21. E.g., Richard v. Broussard, 378 So. 2d 959, 968 (La. Ct. App. 1979); R &
K Bluebonnet, 521 So. 2d at 635.
22. See infra Parts II.B.1., III.B.
23. See infra Part III.A.
24. See infra Part III.B; see a lso Meadowcrest Ctr. v. T enet Health Sys.
Hosps., Inc., 902 So. 2d 512, 514 (La. Ct. App. 2005).
25. See LA. CIV. CODE art. 697 (2017) (establishing that parties can contract
to create predial servitudes upon the ir land or to benefit their land). Unless
specifically excluded, things, including incorporeal property rights, ma y be
bought and sold in Louisiana through contracts of sale. Id. art. 2448. Money,
sometimes cal led wealth, can be used to purchase things in a contract of sale.
Money, BLACKS LAW DICTIONARY 1096 (9th ed. 2009); LA. CIV. CODE arts.
2448, 2464. No language in article 697 or an y other code article prohibits parties
from gra nting pr edial servitudes on their property in exc hange for money in a
contract of sale. It follows that persons with sufficient wealth could purchase a
large number of servitudes that restrict competition. A glut of servitudes
precluding trade, all located within an area and benefitting the same estate, would
make the owner of the dominant estate the only person who could operate a
particular business in that area.
26. See infra Part IV.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT