Push or pull? Performance‐pay, incentives, and information

Published date01 March 2020
AuthorYu Chen,David Rietzke
Date01 March 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12314
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.51, No. 1, Spring 2020
pp. 301–317
Push or pull? Performance-pay, incentives,
and information
David Rietzke
and
Yu Chen∗∗,†
We study a principal-agent model wherein the agent is better informed of the prospects of the
project, and the project requires both an observable and unobservable input. We characterize the
optimal contracts, and explore the trade-offs between high- and low-powered incentive schemes.
We discuss the implications for push and pull programs used to encourage Research and Devel-
opment (R&D) activity, but our results are relevant in other contexts.
1. Introduction
To what extent should incentives be tied to performance? This question is relevant in many
areas, including labor markets—where it relates to the debate on salaries versus piece rates (see,
e.g., Lazear, 1986, 2000)—and innovation incentives, where it pertains to the efficacy of “push”
and “pull” programs (see, e.g., Kremer, 2002). Push programs, such as research grants or R&D
tax credits, subsidize inputs; payments are not contingent on results. Pull programs, such as
inducement prizes, or patent buyouts, tie rewards to output.
Adverse selection (AS) and moral hazard (MH) are inherent challenges in incentive provi-
sion. Given these problems, Kremer (2002) raises the concerns that push programs may finance
projects unlikely to succeed, and provide weak incentives for unobservable inputs. Indeed, the
MH literature stresses the importance of performance-pay; in the canonical model,1compensation
Lancaster University; d.rietzke@lancaster.ac.uk.
∗∗University of Graz.
A previous Working Paper was circulated under the title, “Push or pull? Grants, prizes, and information.” We thank
the Editor, David Martimort, and three anonymous referees for substantially improving the article. We also thank Stan
Reynolds, Andreas Blume, Asaf Plan, John Wooders, Martin Dufwenberg,Rabah Amir, Derek Lemoine, Dakshina De
Silva, Brian Roberson, Junichiro Ishida, Matthew Mitchell, Tim Flannery, Dominik Grafenhofer, Dawen Meng, and
Bo Chen. Finally, we thank participants at the Lancaster University Conference on Auctions, Competition, Regulation,
and Public Policy (May 2015, Lancaster, UK), EARIE Conference (August 2015, Munich, Germany), and the TILEC
Conference on Competition, Standardization, and Innovation (December 2015, Amsterdam, The Netherlands). Chen
gratefully acknowledges financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (grant no. 71673133)
and the National Social Science Fund of China (grant no. 16BJL035).
YuChen unexpectedly passed away in early 2019. He was a great friend and coauthor, and will be sincerely missed.
1See, for example, Grossman and Hart (1983) or Bolton and Dewatripont (2005).
C2020, The RAND Corporation. 301
302 / THE RAND JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
must be tied to output to provide an incentive for effort. Yet, low-powered incentives in which
compensation is weakly, or not at all, tied to performance, are commonly used. In this article,
we explore trade-offs between high- and low-powered incentives in a model with AS and MH.
We show that performance-pay may not be optimal for all types, but is always optimal for the
highest types.
We consider a principal-agent model wherein a risk-neutral funder (he; the principal) moti-
vates a risk-neutral researcher (she; the agent) to undertake an R&D project. The outcome depends
on the researcher’s private type, and two essential and complementary inputs—“investment” and
“effort.” Investment is contractible; effort is not. 2If she succeeds, the researcher profits by mar-
keting the technology,but this incentive is insufficient from the funder’s perspective.To motivate
greater R&D activity, the funder specifies a transfer independent of performance—a “grant”–and
a payment for success—a “prize.”
Our results reveal that the virtues of performance-pay depend on the relative strengths of
AS and MH. In our model, a prize creates a strong incentive for effort, but generates costly rent
for the researcher due to AS. A grant effectively limits rent, but creates only an indirect incentive
for effort (by motivating investment). The virtue of the prize depends on the balance of these
trade-offs. In some circumstances, the optimal prize is zero for a range of types. For high enough
types, however, the prize is alwaysstrictly positive; moreover, when MH is more severe,the prize
is strictly positive for all types.
We contribute to the contracting literature under AS/MH. In many models, output is the
only verifiable signal available to the principal.3This renders performance-pay indispensable, as
output-independent rewards will not affect marginal incentives. Although it may be infeasible to
monitor research effort, some inputs, such as large-scale capital investments, may be easier to
verify. If so, then investment can be encouraged with rewards tied only to these expenditures.
However, a researcher’s effort may be more productive when she has better equipment with
which to work. Then, as long as there is some benefit to success, greater investment increases the
marginal returns to effort. A similar intuition obtains in multitasking models (e.g., H¨
olmstrom
and Milgrom, 1991; Meng and Tian, 2013). Given multiple complementary tasks, a stronger
incentive on one task induces greater effort on others.
We also contribute to the literature on innovation incentives under MH, which has largely
focused on pull programs. For instance, there is a large literature on optimal patent design
(e.g., Gilbert and Shapiro, 1990; Klemperer, 1990; O’Donoghue, Scotchmer, and Thisse, 1998;
Cornelli and Schankerman, 1999; Hopenhayn and Mitchell, 2001; Hall, 2007), and a literature on
alternatives to intellectual property such as prizes or contracts; (e.g., Wright, 1983; Kremer, 1998;
Shavell and Van Ypersele, 2001; Hopenhayn, Llobet, and Mitchell, 2006; Weyl and Tirole, 2012;
Che, Iossa, and Rey, 2015). However, few studies have examined the interactions between push
and pull programs taking MH into account. Maurer and Scotchmer (2003) argue that repeated
interaction between grantees and grantors resolves the MH problem. Our insights complement
theirs, as they are relevant in a static setting. Fu, Lu, and Lu (2012) showthat g rants mayfacilitate
greater competition in a contest between researchers with asymmetric capital endowments. We
abstract from competition to focus on the role of information.
Many studies have explored trade-offs between high- and low-powered incentives. Due to
the “effort-substitution problem,” H¨
olmstrom and Milgrom (1991) show the potential for “fixed-
wage” contracts.4This fixed wageis independent of any signal received by the principal; the grant
in our model depends on investment, but is independent of performance. Baker (1992) shows that
performance-pay may be muted if performance is weakly correlated with verifiable measures.
Low-powered incentives may also arise as a means of risk-sharing (see, e.g., Prendergast, 1999);
2Weuse the ter ms “observable,”“contractible,” and “verifiable” interchangeably.
3Studies close to this analysis include Lewis and Sappington (2000a), Lewis and Sappington (2000b), and Ollier
and Thomas (2013). There are notable exceptions, which will be discussed.
4The effort-substitution problem arises in multitasking models when efforts are substitutes. As a result, a stronger
incentive on one task reduces effort on the other task.
C
The RAND Corporation 2020.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT